- Главная
- Английский язык
- taxes 2021 BATIS
Содержание
- 2. Chapter 1: TAXATION AND ITS ECONOMIC EFFECTS Overview of Taxation Principles A tax (from the Latin
- 3. Tax Collection In modern taxation systems, governments levy taxes in money; but in-kind and corvée taxation
- 4. Purposes of Taxation Purposes of Taxation The levying of taxes aims to raise revenue to fund
- 5. Economic Effects of Taxation Economic Effects of Taxation Imposition of taxes may have the following effects:
- 6. Tax Incidence Tax incidence is the division of the burden of a tax between buyers and
- 7. Example 1: Tax on Sellers Assume a tax per unit of $3 is levied on suppliers
- 9. Consumers purchase 425 units and pay $6/unit. Effectively prices paid by consumers have gone up by
- 10. Example 2: Why taxes result in deadweight losses Imagine that Joe cleans Jane’s house each week
- 11. Example 3: Tax on Buyers Now assume that instead of being levied upon producers, the same
- 12. The impact of a tax on a market outcome is the same whether the tax is
- 13. Tax Incidence and Elasticity of Demand The division of the tax between buyers and sellers depends
- 14. Economic Effects of Taxation
- 15. Demand is perfectly inelastic at 100,000 doses a day, regardless of the price, as shown by
- 16. The demand for this good is perfectly elastic — the demand curve is horizontal. When a
- 17. Tax Incidence and Elasticity of Supply The division of the tax between buyers and sellers also
- 19. The supply of this good is perfectly inelastic at 100,000 bottles a week, as shown by
- 20. The supply of this good is perfectly elastic — the supply curve is horizontal. With no
- 21. Example 8: The burden of tax Depending on the circumstance, the burden of tax can fall
- 22. In the tobacco example, the tax burden falls on the most inelastic side of the market.
- 23. When a tax is introduced in a market with an inelastic supply (see Fig. A) —
- 24. In Fig. A, the supply is inelastic and the demand is elastic — as it is
- 25. The tax revenue is given by the shaded area, which is obtained by multiplying the tax
- 26. In figure A, the tax burden falls disproportionately on the sellers, and a larger proportion of
- 27. On the other hand, if we go back to our example of cigarette taxes, the situation
- 28. Practice Problem 1: The original equilibrium price is €3.00 and the equilibrium quantity is 100. The
- 29. Other economic effects of taxation Redistribution of Income This effect is felt most in developing countries.
- 30. Other economic effects of taxation A Reduction in Incentive It may be argued that increased taxation
- 31. Other economic effects of taxation 3. A Reduction in Business Activity Entrepreneurs undertake investment in anticipation
- 32. Other economic effects of taxation 4. Effects on the Ability to Work, Save and Invest Imposition
- 33. Other economic effects of taxation It is suggested that effects of taxes upon the willingness to
- 34. Laffer Curve The Laffer Curve is a theory developed by supply-side economist Arthur Laffer to show
- 35. Chapter 2: BASIC PRINCIPLES OF TAXATION Goals of an Ideal Taxing System Principles of taxation vary
- 36. 1. Equality Taxpayers should bear a fair level of tax relative to their economic positions (e.g.,
- 37. Vertical equity: When taxpayers are in different economic positions, the taxpayer with the greatest ability to
- 38. 2. Certainty Taxpayer knows when, how, and how much tax is paid. It would protect the
- 39. Tax Base Taxes are computed by multiplying the tax rate by the tax base, that is:
- 40. Tax Deduction Tax deduction is a reduction of income that is able to be taxed and
- 41. Example 12: Tax Credit (U.S. Example) As the simplified example in the table shows, a tax
- 42. Tax Rates For most taxes there are four types of tax rates: statutory rates marginal rates
- 43. Example 13: At the end of the year, XYZ Corporation has taxable income of $50,000. Its
- 44. Example 14: Effective tax rate The company reports the following financial data: Assume that the company
- 45. Effective Tax Rate vs. Marginal Tax Rate The effective tax rate is a more accurate representation
- 46. Example 15: Assume the progressive income-tax system, where taxes are imposed as follows: Consider two individuals
- 47. Tax Rate Structures In most tax jurisdictions, a tax rate structure applies to ordinary income (such
- 48. Though many countries have a progressive tax regime when it comes to income tax, certain levies
- 49. Example 17: U.S. User Fees (regressive) User fees levied by the U.S. government are another form
- 50. Other examples of regressive taxes Gambling taxes Those on low incomes have a high propensity to
- 51. A progressive tax system is one in which the average tax rate (taxes paid ÷ personal
- 52. Example 20: Calculation of Tax Due on Taxable Income (progressive tax structure) In a progressive rate
- 53. A proportional tax system (a.k.a., flat tax system) is the one in which a tax imposed
- 54. Important Principles and Concepts in Tax Law Most tax systems have developed around fundamental concepts that
- 55. Entity Principle Under the entity principle, an entity (such as a corporation) and its owners (for
- 56. Arm’s Length Principle The condition or the fact that the parties to a transaction are independent
- 57. Example 24: Arm’s Length Principle Assume that in Example 23 the corporation pays its entire $250,000
- 58. Example 25: Arm’s Length Test Assume that an entrepreneur sells an asset to his corporation, and
- 59. Arm’s Length Principle: Business Expenses Ordinary and necessary business expenses are deductible only to the extent
- 60. Example 27: Business Deductions Assume John hired four part-time employees and paid them $10 an hour
- 61. All-Inclusive Income Principle This principle basically means that if some simple tests are met, then receipt
- 62. Example 28: Realization Principle A corporation owns two assets that have gone up in value. It
- 63. Business Purpose Concept Relates to tax deductions. Here, business expenses are deductible only if they have
- 64. Tax-Benefit Rule Under the tax-benefit rule, if a taxpayer receives a refund of an item for
- 65. Substance over Form Doctrine Under the doctrine of substance over form, even when the form of
- 66. Pay-As-You-Earn Concept (PAYE) Taxpayers must pay part of their estimated annual tax liability throughout the year,
- 67. Taxation of Gains and Losses on Property Sale In virtually every tax jurisdiction, only the net
- 68. Example 33: Calculation of Gain / Loss A corporation buys a factory building for $2 million
- 69. Chapter 3: PERSONAL INCOME TAX Definition of Personal Income Tax According to OECD, tax on personal
- 70. Example 34: Personal Income Tax Calculation (U.S. example) Resident alien husband and wife with two children;
- 71. The calculation of personal income taxes due (or refund) is based on the following simplified formula:
- 72. Explanations: Gross income may include: income from a job, business income, retirement income, interest income, dividend
- 73. Appendix 1 Source: Spilker, Ayers: Taxation of Individuals and Business Entities, McGraw-Hill, 2019 Edition
- 74. Exclusions and Deferrals Certain tax provisions allow taxpayers to permanently exclude specific types of realized income
- 75. Adjusted Gross Income (AGI) It can be shown that Some common For AGI deductions are: Contribution
- 76. From AGI Deductions After calculating AGI, the taxpayer can then apply: standard deductions to reach their
- 77. Itemized Deduction An expenditure on eligible products, services, or contributions that can be subtracted from adjusted
- 78. Tax Rates After determining taxable income, taxpayers can generally calculate their regular income tax liability using
- 79. Tax Prepayments These include: withholdings, or income taxes withheld from the taxpayer’s salary or wages by
- 80. Example 35: Personal Income Tax Calculation (UK example) In 2017-18, Kenneth (who is not a Scottish
- 81. A typical structure of an income tax computation for year 2017-18 may appear as follows: Personal
- 82. Explanations: Total income may include: Employment income, Pensions, Social security income, Trading income, Property income, Interest,
- 83. Savings Income and Non-Savings Income Tax liability on a taxpayer's "savings income" is calculated differently from
- 84. Tax reliefs may include: Certain payments made by the taxpayer (e.g., eligible interest payments, certain “annual
- 85. Tax rates Income tax is charged on the taxable income, using the tax rates in force
- 86. Tax Treatment of Savings Income Savings income which falls into the first £5,000 (for 2017-18) of
- 87. Personal Savings Allowance (PSA) Taxpayers may be entitled to a PSA of up to £1,000 for
- 88. Example 36: Personal Income Tax Calculation (UK example) In 2017-18, Robert has business profits of £39,700
- 89. Example 37: Personal Income Tax Calculation (UK example) In 2017-18, Roberta has rental income of £15,700
- 90. Example 38: In 2017-18, Philip (who is not a Scottish taxpayer) has business profits of £240,235
- 91. Chapter 4: TAXATION OF INVESTMENT INCOME Definition of Investment Income Investment income is income that comes
- 92. Taxation of Interest and Dividends (US. Case) For tax purposes, individual investors typically are taxed on
- 93. Example 39: Assume Courtney (head of household filing status) decides to purchase dividend-paying stocks to achieve
- 94. Example 39: Assume Courtney (head of household filing status) decides to purchase dividend-paying stocks to achieve
- 95. Example 39: Assume Courtney (head of household filing status) decides to purchase dividend-paying stocks to achieve
- 96. Taxation of Capital Gains and Losses (US. Case) A capital gains tax is a tax on
- 97. FIFO method and Specific Identification Method When taxpayers sell a capital asset, e.g., stock, they may
- 98. Example 41: Assume Courtney sold 200 shares of Cisco stock at the current market price of
- 99. Example 41: Assume Courtney sold 200 shares of Cisco stock at the current market price of
- 100. Short-Term Capital Gains vs. Long-Term Capital Gains Taxpayers selling capital assets they have held for a
- 101. Tax Loss Harvesting Many tax jurisdictions allow realized capital losses to offset realized capital gains. However,
- 102. Tax Loss Harvesting Example 41a: Eduardo has a €1,000,000 portfolio held in a taxable account. The
- 103. Tax Loss Harvesting Example 41a: Eduardo has a €1,000,000 portfolio held in a taxable account. The
- 104. Tax Loss Harvesting
- 105. Taxation of Interest and Dividends (UK Case) Interest received by a taxpayer is charged to income
- 106. Example 42: In 2017-18, Alfred had business profits of £15,870 and received net debenture interest of
- 107. The income tax liability on a taxpayer's dividend income is calculated differently from the liability on
- 108. Example 43: In tax year 2017-18, Christopher has rental income of £24,590. He also receives bank
- 109. Example 43: In tax year 2017-18, Christopher has rental income of £24,590. He also receives bank
- 110. Example 43: In tax year 2017-18, Christopher has rental income of £24,590. He also receives bank
- 111. Capital Gains Tax (UK Case) For tax year 2017-18, there are two main rates of capital
- 112. Capital Gains Tax: Basis of Assessment A person's CGT liability for a tax year is based
- 113. (c) If there are net gains for the year, these are reduced first by any unrelieved
- 114. Example 44: Four taxpayers each make three chargeable disposals during 2017-18. Compute their taxable gains for
- 115. Example 44: Four taxpayers each make three chargeable disposals during 2017-18. Compute their taxable gains for
- 116. Calculation of Capital Gains Tax Payable CGT rates are applied to the taxable gains which remain
- 117. Example 45: Calculate the amount of CGT payable for 2017-18 by each of the following individuals.
- 118. Example 45: Calculate the amount of CGT payable for 2017-18 by each of the following individuals.
- 119. Example 45: Calculate the amount of CGT payable for 2017-18 by each of the following individuals.
- 120. Example 45: Calculate the amount of CGT payable for 2017-18 by each of the following individuals.
- 121. Example 45: Calculate the amount of CGT payable for 2017-18 by each of the following individuals.
- 122. Example 45: Calculate the amount of CGT payable for 2017-18 by each of the following individuals.
- 123. Example 45: Calculate the amount of CGT payable for 2017-18 by each of the following individuals.
- 124. Example 45: Calculate the amount of CGT payable for 2017-18 by each of the following individuals.
- 125. Example 45: Calculate the amount of CGT payable for 2017-18 by each of the following individuals.
- 126. Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns After-Tax Accumulations and Returns for Taxable Accounts Taxes on investment
- 127. Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns There are two types of methods of taxation: Accrual taxes
- 128. Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns The amount of money accumulated for each unit of currency
- 129. Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns Tax Drag on Capital Accumulation Tax drag is a reduction
- 130. Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns Example 47: John is determining the impact of taxes on
- 131. Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns Implications of tax drag (assuming accrual taxation) When investment returns
- 132. Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns 2. Returns-Based Taxes: Deferred Capital Gains Deferred capital gain taxes
- 133. Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns Example 48: Assume that €100 are invested at 6% per
- 134. Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns Implications of tax drag (assuming taxes on capital gains are
- 135. Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns 3. Wealth-Based Taxes Some jurisdictions impose a wealth tax, which
- 136. Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns If wealth is taxed annually at a rate of tw,
- 137. Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns Implications of tax drag (assuming tax on wealth) Tax drag
- 138. Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns Example 51: Olga lives in a country that imposes a
- 139. Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns Blended Taxing Environments In reality, investment portfolios are subject to
- 140. Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns It can be shown that: Total realized tax rate =
- 141. Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns Example 52: Michael has a balanced portfolio of stocks and
- 142. Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns Example 52: Michael has a balanced portfolio of stocks and
- 143. Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns Example 52: Michael has a balanced portfolio of stocks and
- 144. Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns Example 52: Michael has a balanced portfolio of stocks and
- 145. Chapter 5: CORPORATION TAX Definition of Corporate Tax Corporate tax (a.k.a. corporation tax) is a direct
- 146. Corporate Tax Rates International Corporate Tax Rates Corporate tax rates vary widely by country, leading some
- 147. The calculation of corporate income taxes due (or refund) is based on the following simplified formula:
- 148. Explanations: Gross income may include: gross profit from inventory sales (sales minus cost of goods sold),
- 149. Some common business deductions are: Ordinary and necessary business expenses Corporate Income Tax Calculation Examples 2
- 150. Some limitations on business deductions: Capital expenditures (e.g., expenditures for tangible assets such as buildings, machinery,
- 151. Business interest expense Deduction for business interest expense is limited to the sum of business interest
- 152. Computing corporate taxable income To compute taxable income, most corporations begin with book (financial reporting) income
- 153. In addition to the favorable/unfavorable distinction, book–tax differences can be categorized as permanent or temporary. •
- 154. Some Common Permanent Book-Tax Differences Corporate Income Tax Calculation Examples Source: Spilker, Ayers: Taxation of Individuals
- 155. • Temporary book–tax differences arise in one year and reverse in a subsequent year. Corporations experience
- 156. Some Common Temporary Book-Tax Differences Corporate Income Tax Calculation Examples *Note that each of the initial
- 157. Corporate-Specific Deductions and Book-Tax Differences Net Capital Losses For corporations, all net capital gains (long- and
- 158. Example 53: Book–Tax Reconciliation Template Source: Spilker, Ayers: Taxation of Individuals and Business Entities, McGraw-Hill, 2019
- 159. Example 53: Book–Tax Reconciliation Template Capital losses of $28,000 are not deducted for tax purposes (unfavorable
- 160. Example 53: Book–Tax Reconciliation Template Initial estimated fair value of stock options is deducted in books,
- 161. Example 53: Book–Tax Reconciliation Template Temporary book-tax differences
- 162. Example 53: Book–Tax Reconciliation Template Business-related meal expenses of $28,000 are fully deductible for books but
- 163. Example 53: Book–Tax Reconciliation Template Corporations deduct federal income tax expense in determining their book income.
- 164. Example 53: Book–Tax Reconciliation Template Corporations are allowed a deduction for dividends received to help mitigate
- 165. Corporate income tax liability: When corporations calculate their taxable income, they compute their tax liability using
- 166. Scope of Corporation Tax (U.K. case) A company's taxable total profits include both its income and
- 167. Calculation of company’s taxable total profits may be summarized as follows: Corporate Income Tax Calculation Examples
- 168. Calculation of company’s taxable total profits may be summarized as follows: Corporate Income Tax Calculation Examples
- 169. Notes: Trading income consists of company’s trading profit for an accounting period, as adjusted for tax
- 170. Example 54: Calculation of a company’s trading income (UK case) A company's income statement for the
- 171. 2. Administrative expenses are as follows: Corporate Income Tax Calculation Examples Compute the company's trading income
- 172. Solution: Corporate Income Tax Calculation Examples Gift Aid donations are disallowed when computing trading income but
- 173. Solution: Corporate Income Tax Calculation Examples Losses caused by the dishonesty of a director are disallowed.
- 174. Computation of Corporation Tax Liability (U.K. case) Given a company's taxable total profits (TTP) for an
- 175. Chapter 6: INDIRECT TAXES: VALUE-ADDED TAX Definition of Value Added Tax Value added tax (VAT) is
- 176. Map of countries and territories by their VAT status VAT No VAT
- 177. Standard VAT or sales tax rate
- 178. Value Added Tax Rates in Europe
- 179. VAT Calculation Principles A VAT is levied on the gross margin at each point in the
- 180. Example 55: Value Added Tax Assume a VAT of 10%. A farmer sells wheat to a
- 181. Example 55: Value Added Tax The baker uses the wheat to make bread and sells a
- 182. Example 55: Value Added Tax Finally, the supermarket sells the loaf of bread to a customer
- 183. VAT vs. Sales Tax Sales tax is assessed only once at the final stage of the
- 184. VAT: Advantages Adoption of a regressive tax system, such as VAT, gives people a stronger incentive
- 185. VAT: Disadvantages Unlike the income tax rate, which varies at different levels of income, VAT is
- 186. Value Added Tax (U.K. case) The basic principle of VAT is that tax should be charged
- 187. Example 57: A Ltd owns a quarry. It extracts stone from this quarry and sells it
- 188. Example 57: A Ltd owns a quarry. It extracts stone from this quarry and sells it
- 189. Chapter 7: INTERNATIONAL TAXATION ASPECTS Taxation Systems Countries that tax income generally use one of two
- 191. Taxation of income Under source jurisdiction a country levies taxes on all income generated within its
- 192. Double Taxation Conflicts Interaction of country tax systems can result in tax conflicts in which two
- 193. Foreign Tax Credit Provisions A residence country may choose to unilaterally provide its taxpayers relief from
- 194. Foreign Tax Credit Provisions A residence country may choose to unilaterally provide its taxpayers relief from
- 195. Foreign Tax Credit Provisions A residence country may choose to unilaterally provide its taxpayers relief from
- 196. Foreign Tax Credit Provisions A residence country may choose to unilaterally provide its taxpayers relief from
- 197. Foreign Tax Credit Provisions A residence country may choose to unilaterally provide its taxpayers relief from
- 198. Foreign Tax Credit Provisions A residence country may choose to unilaterally provide its taxpayers relief from
- 199. Foreign Tax Credit Provisions A residence country may choose to unilaterally provide its taxpayers relief from
- 200. Foreign Tax Credit Provisions A residence country may choose to unilaterally provide its taxpayers relief from
- 201. Double Taxation Treaties Relief from double taxation may be provided through a double taxation treaty (DTT)
- 202. Double Taxation Treaties In addition to residence–source conflicts, DTTs resolve residence–residence conflicts. A resident is taxable
- 203. Tax Avoidance vs. Tax Evasion Tax avoidance (a.k.a. “tax minimization”) uses legal means to lower the
- 204. Current Trends in International Transparency and Information Exchange Most countries attempt to maximize the amount of
- 205. Current Trends in International Transparency and Information Exchange Most countries attempt to maximize the amount of
- 206. Current Trends in International Transparency and Information Exchange Most countries attempt to maximize the amount of
- 207. Common Tax Evasion Schemes Falsifying information on tax return This occurs when a taxpayer understates its
- 208. Transfer Pricing Transfer pricing is an accounting practice that represents the price that one division in
- 209. Example 62: Transfer Pricing as a Tax Reduction Strategy A U.S. parent has an overseas subsidiary,
- 210. Example 62: Transfer Pricing as a Tax Reduction Strategy A U.S. parent has an overseas subsidiary,
- 211. Example 62: Transfer Pricing as a Tax Reduction Strategy A U.S. parent has an overseas subsidiary,
- 212. Example 62: Transfer Pricing as a Tax Reduction Strategy A U.S. parent has an overseas subsidiary,
- 213. Example 62: Transfer Pricing as a Tax Reduction Strategy A U.S. parent has an overseas subsidiary,
- 214. Transfer Pricing via Tax Haven Transfer pricing is a technique used by multinational corporations to shift
- 215. Tax Haven A tax haven (a.k.a., offshore financial center) is a tax jurisdiction with very low
- 217. Скачать презентацию
Слайд 2Chapter 1: TAXATION AND ITS ECONOMIC EFFECTS
Overview of Taxation Principles
A tax (from
Chapter 1: TAXATION AND ITS ECONOMIC EFFECTS
Overview of Taxation Principles
A tax (from
Most countries have a tax system in place to pay for public, common or agreed national needs and government functions.
Some levy a flat percentage rate of taxation on personal annual income, but most scale taxes based on annual income amounts.
Most countries charge a tax on individual income as well as on corporate income.
Countries often also impose wealth taxes, inheritance taxes, estate taxes, gift taxes, property taxes, sales taxes, payroll taxes or tariffs.
Слайд 3Tax Collection
In modern taxation systems, governments levy taxes in money; but in-kind
Tax Collection
In modern taxation systems, governments levy taxes in money; but in-kind
The method of taxation and the government expenditure of taxes raised is often highly debated in politics and economics.
Tax collection is performed by a government agency, for example:
Canada Revenue Agency,
Internal Revenue Service (IRS) in the United States,
Her Majesty's Revenue and Customs (HMRC) in the UK
Federal Tax Service in Russia
VID in Latvia.
When taxes are not fully paid, the state may impose civil penalties (such as fines or forfeiture) or criminal penalties (such as incarceration) on the non-paying entity or individual.
Слайд 4Purposes of Taxation
Purposes of Taxation
The levying of taxes aims to
raise revenue
Purposes of Taxation
Purposes of Taxation
The levying of taxes aims to
raise revenue
alter prices in order to affect demand.
Governments use money provided by taxation to carry out many functions, e.g.:
expenditures on economic infrastructure (roads, public transportation, sanitation, legal systems, public safety, education, health-care systems),
military,
scientific research,
culture and the arts,
public insurance, and
the operation of government itself.
A government's ability to raise taxes is called its fiscal capacity.
When expenditures exceed tax revenue, a government accumulates debt. A portion of taxes may be used to service past debts.
Слайд 5Economic Effects of Taxation
Economic Effects of Taxation
Imposition of taxes may have the
Economic Effects of Taxation
Economic Effects of Taxation
Imposition of taxes may have the
Taxes cause an income effect because they reduce purchasing power to taxpayers.
Taxes cause a substitution effect when taxation causes a substitution between taxed goods and untaxed goods.
Both buyers and sellers are worse off when a good is taxed:
A tax raises the price buyers pay and lowers the price sellers receive. This can be shown with the concept of a tax incidence.
Слайд 6Tax Incidence
Tax incidence is the division of the burden of a tax
Tax Incidence
Tax incidence is the division of the burden of a tax
When the government imposes a tax on the sale of a good or services, the price paid by buyers might rise by:
the full amount of the tax,
a lesser amount, or
not at all.
If the price paid by buyers rises by the full amount of the tax, then the burden of the tax falls entirely on buyers—the buyers pay the tax.
If the price paid by buyers rises by a lesser amount than the tax, then the burden of the tax falls partly on buyers and partly on sellers.
And if the price paid by buyers doesn’t change at all, then the burden of the tax falls entirely on sellers.
Economic Effects of Taxation
Слайд 7Example 1:
Tax on Sellers
Assume a tax per unit of $3 is levied
Example 1:
Tax on Sellers
Assume a tax per unit of $3 is levied
Economic Effects of Taxation
Слайд 9Consumers purchase 425 units and pay $6/unit. Effectively prices paid by consumers
Consumers purchase 425 units and pay $6/unit. Effectively prices paid by consumers
Producers sell 425 units at $6/unit but only pocket $3/unit after paying the tax. Effectively, their realized prices have fallen by $4 − $3 = $1. Producer surplus has therefore fallen by Rectangle C and Triangle D.
The government earns tax revenue of $3/unit on 425 units that are sold. So part of the loss in consumer surplus (Rectangle A) and producer surplus (Rectangle C) is transferred to the government.
However, some consumer surplus (Triangle B) and producer surplus (Triangle D) remains untransferred and is lost due to the imposition of the tax. These two triangles comprise society’s deadweight loss.
Even though this tax was levied on suppliers only, consumers and producers share the
actual burden of the tax as consumer and producer surplus both decline once the tax is
imposed.
Further, in our example, consumers actually end up bearing the brunt of the tax in the form of an effective increase in prices of $2, versus an effective decrease in producer realized prices of only $1. Note that consumer surplus transferred to the government, Rectangle A, is greater than producer surplus transferred to the government, Rectangle C. This is because the demand curve is steeper than the supply curve. If the supply curve were steeper, the reverse would be true regardless of whom the tax was imposed upon by law.
Economic Effects of Taxation
Слайд 10Example 2:
Why taxes result in deadweight losses
Imagine that Joe cleans Jane’s house
Example 2:
Why taxes result in deadweight losses
Imagine that Joe cleans Jane’s house
Now suppose that the government levies a €50 tax on the providers of cleaning services. There is now no price that Jane can pay Joe that will leave both of them better off. The most Jane would be willing to pay is €120, but then Joe would be left with only €70 after paying the tax, which is less than his €80 opportunity cost.
Conversely, for Joe to receive his opportunity cost of €80, Jane would need to pay €130, which is above the €120 value she places on a clean house. As a result, Jane and Joe cancel their arrangement. Joe goes without the income, and Jane lives in a dirtier house.
The tax has made Joe and Jane worse off by a total of €40 because they have each lost €20 of surplus. But note that the government collects no revenue from Joe and Jane because they decide to cancel their arrangement. The €40 is pure deadweight loss: It is a loss to buyers and sellers in a market that is not offset by an increase in government revenue. From this example, we can see the ultimate source of deadweight losses: Taxes cause deadweight losses because they prevent buyers and sellers from realizing some of the gains from trade.
Economic Effects of Taxation
Слайд 11Example 3:
Tax on Buyers
Now assume that instead of being levied upon producers,
Example 3:
Tax on Buyers
Now assume that instead of being levied upon producers,
Economic Effects of Taxation
Слайд 12The impact of a tax on a market outcome is the same
The impact of a tax on a market outcome is the same
When a tax is levied on buyers, the demand curve shifts downward by the size of the tax;
when it is levied on sellers, the supply curve shifts upward by that amount.
In either case, when the tax is enacted, the price paid by buyers rises, and the price received by sellers falls.
In the end, the elasticities of supply and demand determine how the tax burden is distributed between producers and consumers. This distribution is the same regardless of how it is levied.
Economic Effects of Taxation
Слайд 13Tax Incidence and Elasticity of Demand
The division of the tax between buyers
Tax Incidence and Elasticity of Demand
The division of the tax between buyers
Price elasticity of demand is a measure of the responsiveness of the quantity demanded of a good to a change in its price when all other influences on buying plans remain the same.
There are two extreme cases:
Perfectly inelastic demand Buyers pay the entire tax.
Perfectly elastic demand Sellers pay the entire tax.
Also, the more inelastic the demand (relative to supply), the larger is the buyers’ share of the tax.
See Fig. 1 and 2 (next slide)
Economic Effects of Taxation
Слайд 14Economic Effects of Taxation
Economic Effects of Taxation
Слайд 15Demand is perfectly inelastic at 100,000 doses a day, regardless of the
Demand is perfectly inelastic at 100,000 doses a day, regardless of the
If insulin is taxed at 20¢ a dose we must add the tax to the minimum price at which drug companies are willing to sell insulin. The result is the new supply curve S + tax.
When a tax is imposed on this good, buyers pay the entire tax.
Economic Effects of Taxation
Example 4:
Tax with Perfectly Inelastic Demand
Figure shows the market for insulin, a vital daily medication for those
with diabetes.
Слайд 16The demand for this good is perfectly elastic — the demand curve
The demand for this good is perfectly elastic — the demand curve
When a tax of 10¢ is imposed on this good, sellers pay the entire tax.
Economic Effects of Taxation
Example 5:
Tax with Perfectly Elastic Demand
Figure shows the market for pink marker pens.
Слайд 17Tax Incidence and Elasticity of Supply
The division of the tax between buyers
Tax Incidence and Elasticity of Supply
The division of the tax between buyers
The elasticity of supply measures the responsiveness of the quantity supplied to a change in the price of a good, when all other influences on selling plans remain the same.
Again, there are two extreme cases:
Perfectly inelastic supply Sellers pay the entire tax.
Perfectly elastic supply Buyers pay the entire tax.
Also, the more elastic the supply (relative to demand), the larger is the amount of the tax paid by buyers.
See Fig. 3 and 4 (next slide)
Economic Effects of Taxation
Слайд 19The supply of this good is perfectly inelastic at 100,000 bottles a
The supply of this good is perfectly inelastic at 100,000 bottles a
When a tax is imposed on this good at 5¢ a bottle, the supply curve does not change because the spring owners still produce 100,000 bottles a week, even though the price they receive falls. But buyers are willing to buy the 100,000 bottles only if the price is 50¢ a bottle, so the price does not change. The tax reduces the price received by sellers to 45¢ a bottle, and sellers pay the entire tax.
Economic Effects of Taxation
Example 6:
Tax with Perfectly Inelastic Supply
Figure shows the market for water from a mineral spring that flows at a constant rate that cannot be controlled.
Слайд 20The supply of this good is perfectly elastic — the supply curve
The supply of this good is perfectly elastic — the supply curve
When a tax of 1¢ a pound is imposed, we must add it to the minimum supply-price. Sellers are now willing to offer any quantity at 11¢ a pound along the curve S + tax. A new equilibrium is set at a price of 11¢ and 3,000 pounds a week. The tax has increased the price buyers pay by the full amount of the tax – 1¢ a pound – and has decreased the quantity sold. Buyers pay the entire tax.
Economic Effects of Taxation
Example 7:
Tax with Perfectly Elastic Supply
Figure shows the market for sand.
Слайд 21Example 8:
The burden of tax
Depending on the circumstance, the burden of tax
Example 8:
The burden of tax
Depending on the circumstance, the burden of tax
In the case of tobacco products, for example, demand is inelastic — because tobacco is an addictive substance — and taxes are mainly passed along to consumers in the form of higher prices.
Economic Effects of Taxation
Слайд 22In the tobacco example, the tax burden falls on the most inelastic
In the tobacco example, the tax burden falls on the most inelastic
When the demand is inelastic (see Fig. B), consumers are not very responsive to price changes, and the quantity demanded remains relatively constant when the tax is introduced. In the case of smoking, the demand is inelastic because consumers are addicted to the product. The seller can then pass the tax burden along to consumers in the form of higher prices without much of a decline in the equilibrium quantity.
Economic Effects of Taxation
Слайд 23When a tax is introduced in a market with an inelastic supply
When a tax is introduced in a market with an inelastic supply
Economic Effects of Taxation
Слайд 24In Fig. A, the supply is inelastic and the demand is elastic
In Fig. A, the supply is inelastic and the demand is elastic
Economic Effects of Taxation
Слайд 25The tax revenue is given by the shaded area, which is obtained
The tax revenue is given by the shaded area, which is obtained
The tax incidence on the consumers is given by the difference between the price paid, Pc, and the initial equilibrium price, Pe.
The tax incidence on the sellers is given by the difference between the initial equilibrium price, Pe, and the price they receive after the tax is introduced, Pp.
Economic Effects of Taxation
Слайд 26In figure A, the tax burden falls disproportionately on the sellers, and
In figure A, the tax burden falls disproportionately on the sellers, and
Economic Effects of Taxation
Слайд 27On the other hand, if we go back to our example of
On the other hand, if we go back to our example of
Economic Effects of Taxation
Слайд 28Practice Problem 1:
The original equilibrium price is €3.00 and the equilibrium quantity
Practice Problem 1:
The original equilibrium price is €3.00 and the equilibrium quantity
The government then imposes a tax of €0.50 on the sellers. This leads to a new supply curve which is shifted upward by €0.50 compared to the original supply curve.
The new equilibrium price will be in the range between €3.00 and €3.50 and the equilibrium quantity will decrease.
Assume that the consumers pay €3.30 and the new equilibrium quantity is 90.
What is the price that sellers will receive after the tax is imposed?
Pp = Pc – tax
Pp = €3.30 – €0.50 = €2.80 (producers will keep €2.80)
What is the total tax revenue for the government?
The government will collect €0.50(90) = €45
3. Who shares more of the tax burden, sellers or buyers?
Buyers’ share of the tax burden is (€3.30 – €3.00)(90) = €27
Sellers’ share of the tax burden is (€3.00 – €2.80)(90) = €18
Economic Effects of Taxation
Слайд 29Other economic effects of taxation
Redistribution of Income
This effect is felt most in
Other economic effects of taxation
Redistribution of Income
This effect is felt most in
A proportional tax will not affect the distribution of income, but both progressive and regressive taxes will cause a change in income distribution.
With progressive taxes, the post-tax distribution of income is more equal than the pre-tax distribution, whereas with regressive taxes the post-tax distribution is more unequal than the pre-tax distribution.
Economic Effects of Taxation
Слайд 30Other economic effects of taxation
A Reduction in Incentive
It may be argued that
Other economic effects of taxation
A Reduction in Incentive
It may be argued that
However, it may be argued that workers may want to maintain their present standard of living or may have heavy financial commitments so that if income tax was increased, they would work for longer hours to make up for the income lost in tax.
There are, therefore, conflicting views on the effect of incentives.
Economic Effects of Taxation
Слайд 31Other economic effects of taxation
3. A Reduction in Business Activity
Entrepreneurs undertake investment
Other economic effects of taxation
3. A Reduction in Business Activity
Entrepreneurs undertake investment
If, however, profits are heavily taxed, the entrepreneurs may feel that it is not worth taking such risks and so they will be far more cautious in their attitudes.
Such caution may lead to reduced progress and efficiency with a consequent deterioration in the ability of domestic producers to complete with foreign rivals.
Economic Effects of Taxation
Слайд 32Other economic effects of taxation
4. Effects on the Ability to Work, Save
Other economic effects of taxation
4. Effects on the Ability to Work, Save
Imposition of taxes results in the reduction of disposable income of the taxpayers. This will reduce their expenditure on necessaries which are required to be consumed for the sake of improving efficiency.
As efficiency suffers ability to work declines. This ultimately adversely affects savings and investment. However, this happens in the case of poor persons.
Taxation on rich persons has the least effect on the efficiency and ability to work.
Note: Not all taxes, however, have adverse effects on the ability to work. There are some harmful goods, such as cigarettes, whose consumption has to be reduced to increase ability to work. That is why high rate of taxes are often imposed on such harmful goods to curb their consumption.
But all taxes adversely affect ability to save. Since rich people save more than the poor, progressive rate of taxation reduces savings potentiality. This means low level of investment. Lower rate of investment has a dampening effect on economic growth of a country.
Thus, on the whole, taxes have the disincentive effect on the ability to work, save and invest.
Economic Effects of Taxation
Слайд 33Other economic effects of taxation
It is suggested that effects of taxes upon
Other economic effects of taxation
It is suggested that effects of taxes upon
Income elasticity of demand measures the responsiveness of demand for a particular good to a change in income, holding all other things constant.
Income elasticity of demand varies from individual to individual.
If the income demand of an individual taxpayer is inelastic, a cut in income consequent upon the imposition of taxes will induce him to work more and to save more so that the lost income is at least partially recovered.
On the other hand, the desire to work and save of those people whose demand for income is elastic will be affected adversely.
Thus, we have conflicting views on the incentives to work. It would seem logical that there must be a disincentive effect of taxes at some point but it is not clear at what level of taxation that crucial point would be reached.
Economic Effects of Taxation
Слайд 34Laffer Curve
The Laffer Curve is a theory developed by supply-side economist Arthur
Laffer Curve
The Laffer Curve is a theory developed by supply-side economist Arthur
The Laffer Curve describes the relationship between tax rates and total tax revenue, with an optimal tax rate that maximizes total government tax revenue.
Economic Effects of Taxation
If taxes are too high along the Laffer Curve, then they will discourage the taxed activities, such as work and investment, enough to actually reduce total tax revenue.
In this case, cutting tax rates will both stimulate economic incentives and increase tax revenue.
Слайд 35Chapter 2: BASIC PRINCIPLES OF TAXATION
Goals of an Ideal Taxing System
Principles of
Chapter 2: BASIC PRINCIPLES OF TAXATION
Goals of an Ideal Taxing System
Principles of
The basic objective of taxation is to raise revenues to finance governments.
Governments also attempt to achieve other objectives in designing and implementing tax systems. These objectives are frequently complicated by the dynamics of political, economic, and social forces.
People designing tax systems have often considered the criteria for good taxation formulated by Adam Smith (1776):
Equality
Certainty
Convenience
Economy
Слайд 361. Equality
Taxpayers should bear a fair level of tax relative to their
1. Equality
Taxpayers should bear a fair level of tax relative to their
Equality can be defined in terms of horizontal and vertical equity.
Horizontal equity:
Two similarly situated taxpayers are taxed the same.
Example 9:
Bill’s income for the year consists solely of $15,000 in dividends. Ted’s income consists solely of $15,000 in interest income.
Both pay a tax rate of 15%, or $2,250 in taxes; there is horizontal equity.
Example 10:
Corporation A has net income from the sales of widgets of $15,000. Corporation B has net income of $15,000 from the performance of services.
Both pay a tax of $2,250; there is horizontal equity.
Canons of Taxation
Слайд 37Vertical equity:
When taxpayers are in different economic positions, the taxpayer with the
Vertical equity:
When taxpayers are in different economic positions, the taxpayer with the
Example 11:
Refer back to Example 9. Assume, in addition to the $15,000 of income, Bill has an additional $45,000 of dividend income, giving him a total of $60,000 in income.
If he is still taxed a 15% rate, there is no vertical equity;
if he is taxed a higher rate (say, 25%) there may be vertical equity, since Bill pays proportionately more taxes than Ted.
Note:
Income taxes tend to be progressive. That is, higher tax rates apply when there are higher levels of the amount being taxed. For income taxes, this amount—called the tax base—is taxable income.
However, consumption-related taxes (such as VAT) are rarely progressive (and are often considered regressive) because there is typically only one tax rate.
Canons of Taxation
Слайд 382. Certainty
Taxpayer knows when, how, and how much tax is paid.
It
2. Certainty
Taxpayer knows when, how, and how much tax is paid.
It
3. Convenience
Taxes should be levied at the time it is most likely to be convenient for the taxpayer to make the payment. This generally occurs as they receive income because this is when they are most likely to have the ability to pay.
e.g. tax on dividends is usually paid when dividends are received and tax on capital gains is paid when shares are sold
4. Economy
A tax should have minimum compliance and administrative costs. That is, it should require a minimum of time and effort for the taxpayer to calculate and pay the tax. Administrative costs are expenses incurred by the government to collect the tax. Compliance and administrative costs are highest for income taxes, because of their complexity.
Canons of Taxation
Слайд 39Tax Base
Taxes are computed by multiplying the tax rate by the tax
Tax Base
Taxes are computed by multiplying the tax rate by the tax
Tax base is the amount that is subject to tax.
For income taxes, the tax base is taxable income, defined roughly as income less allowable expenses.
For property taxes, the tax base is some measure of the value of the property.
Consumption taxes, such as VAT and sales tax, are most often based on the sales price of the merchandise sold.
For payroll taxes, a common tax base is employment compensation.
Framework for Understanding Taxes
Слайд 40Tax Deduction
Tax deduction is a reduction of income that is able to
Tax Deduction
Tax deduction is a reduction of income that is able to
e.g. A tax deduction reduces the taxable income of a taxpayer. If a single filer’s taxable income for the tax year is $75,000 and he falls in the 25% marginal tax bracket, his total marginal tax bill will be 25% x $75,000 = $18,750. However, if he qualifies for an $8,000 tax deduction, he will be taxed on $75,000 - $8,000 = $67,000 taxable income, not $75,000. The reduction of his taxable income is a tax relief for the taxpayer who ends up paying less in taxes to the government.
Tax Credit
Tax credit is a tax relief that provides more tax savings for an entity than a tax deduction as it directly reduces a taxpayer’s bill, rather than just reducing the amount of income subject to taxes.
In other words, a tax credit is applied to the amount of tax owed by the taxpayer after all deductions are made from his or her taxable income.
e.g. If an individual owes $3,000 to the government and is eligible for a $1,100 tax credit, he will only have to pay $1,900 after the tax relief is applied.
Framework for Understanding Taxes
Слайд 41Example 12:
Tax Credit (U.S. Example)
As the simplified example in the table shows,
Example 12:
Tax Credit (U.S. Example)
As the simplified example in the table shows,
Framework for Understanding Taxes
Слайд 42Tax Rates
For most taxes there are four types of tax rates:
statutory rates
marginal
Tax Rates
For most taxes there are four types of tax rates:
statutory rates
marginal
average rates
effective rates
Statutory tax rate is the legally imposed rate. An income tax could have multiple statutory rates for different income levels, where a sales tax may have a flat statutory rate.
Marginal tax rate is the tax rate that will be paid on the next dollar of tax base (i.e., the rate on the next dollar of income for income taxes).
Average tax rate is computed as the total tax divided by the total tax base.
Framework for Understanding Taxes
Слайд 43Example 13:
At the end of the year, XYZ Corporation has taxable income
Example 13:
At the end of the year, XYZ Corporation has taxable income
1. What is the marginal tax rate?
Marginal tax rate on this income is 25%.
2. What is the average tax rate?
Average tax rate is ($7,500 + $5,000) / $70,000 = 17.9%
Effective tax rate is the average tax rate paid by a corporation or an individual.
The effective tax rate for individuals is the average rate at which their earned income, such as wages, and unearned income, such as stock dividends, are taxed.
The effective tax rate for a corporation is the average rate at which its pre-tax profits are taxed.
Framework for Understanding Taxes
Слайд 44Example 14:
Effective tax rate
The company reports the following financial data:
Assume that the
Example 14:
Effective tax rate
The company reports the following financial data:
Assume that the
As a result, the effective tax rate is reduced by 6 percentage points from 40% to 34% (= 2.04m / 6m) and the after-tax profit increases by 10% to €3,960,000 (= 6,000,000 – 2,040,000).
Framework for Understanding Taxes
Слайд 45Effective Tax Rate vs. Marginal Tax Rate
The effective tax rate is a
Effective Tax Rate vs. Marginal Tax Rate
The effective tax rate is a
The marginal tax rate refers to the highest tax bracket into which their income falls.
In a progressive income-tax system, income is taxed at differing rates that rise as income reaches certain thresholds. Two individuals or companies with income in the same upper marginal tax bracket may end up with very different effective tax rates, depending on how much of their income was in the top bracket.
Framework for Understanding Taxes
Слайд 46Example 15:
Assume the progressive income-tax system, where taxes are imposed as follows:
Example 15:
Assume the progressive income-tax system, where taxes are imposed as follows:
Consider two individuals whose taxable income exceeds $300,000, so both individuals hit the upper tax bracket of 25%.
Assume that individual A has taxable income of $500,000, while individual B has taxable income of $360,000.
For individual A, the overall tax liability would be:
($100,000 – $0) × 0.1 + ($300,000 – $100,000) × 0.15 + ($500,000 – $300,000) × 0.25 = 10,000 + 30,000 + 50,000 = $90,000,
For individual B, the tax liability would be:
($100,000 – $0) × 0.1 + ($300,000 – $100,000) × 0.15 + ($360,000 – $300,000) × 0.25 = 10,000 + 30,000 + 15,000 = $55,000,
While both individuals might say they're in the 25% bracket, the one with the higher income has an effective tax rate of 18% ($90,000 in tax divided by $500,000 in income), while the other's effective tax rate is 15.3% ($55,000 divided by $360,000).
Framework for Understanding Taxes
Слайд 47Tax Rate Structures
In most tax jurisdictions, a tax rate structure applies to
Tax Rate Structures
In most tax jurisdictions, a tax rate structure applies to
Investment income is often taxed differently based on the nature of the income: interest, dividends, or capital gains and losses.
Tax rates vary from country to country. Some countries implement a progressive tax system, while others use regressive or proportional tax rates.
A regressive tax system is one in which the tax rate increases as the taxable amount decreases.
A regressive tax is a tax applied uniformly, taking a larger percentage of income from low-income earners than from high-income earners.
Note: A regressive tax affects people with low incomes more severely than people with high incomes because it is applied uniformly to all situations, regardless of the taxpayer. While it may be fair in some instances to tax everyone at the same rate, it is seen as unjust in other cases. As such, most income tax systems employ a progressive schedule that taxes high-income earners at a higher percentage rate than low-income earners, while other types of taxes are uniformly applied.
Framework for Understanding Taxes
Слайд 48Though many countries have a progressive tax regime when it comes to
Though many countries have a progressive tax regime when it comes to
e.g., in the U.S., some of regressive taxes include state sales taxes, user fees, and, to some degree, property taxes.
Example 16:
U.S. Sales tax (regressive)
Governments apply sales tax uniformly to all consumers based on what they buy. Even though the tax may be uniform (such as a 7% sales tax), lower-income consumers are more affected.
For example, imagine two individuals each purchase $100 of clothing per week, and they each pay $7 in tax on their retail purchases. The first individual earns $2,000 per week, making the sales tax rate on her purchase 0.35% of income. In contrast, the other individual earns $320 per week, making her clothing sales tax 2.2% of income. In this case, although the tax is the same rate in both cases, the person with the lower income pays a higher percentage of income, making the tax regressive.
Framework for Understanding Taxes
Слайд 49Example 17:
U.S. User Fees (regressive)
User fees levied by the U.S. government are
Example 17:
U.S. User Fees (regressive)
User fees levied by the U.S. government are
For example, if two families travel to the Grand Canyon National Park and pay a $30 admission fee, the family with the higher income pays a lower percentage of its income to access the park, while the family with the lower income pays a higher percentage. Although the fee is the same amount, it constitutes a more significant burden on the family with the lower income, again making it a regressive tax.
Example 18:
Property Taxes (regressive)
Property taxes are fundamentally regressive because, if two individuals in the same tax jurisdiction live in properties with the same values, they pay the same amount of property tax, regardless of their incomes.
However, they are not purely regressive in practice because they are based on the value of the property. Generally, it is thought that lower income earners live in less expensive homes, thus partially indexing property taxes to income.
Framework for Understanding Taxes
Слайд 50Other examples of regressive taxes
Gambling taxes
Those on low incomes have a
Other examples of regressive taxes
Gambling taxes
Those on low incomes have a
Fuel tax
Those on high income may spend more on petrol, but it is unlikely to be too significant, therefore as your income rises, the percentage of income going on petrol tax is likely to fall.
Sin taxes
Taxes levied on products that are deemed to be harmful to society.
These are added to the prices of goods like alcohol and tobacco in order to dissuade people from using them.
These taxes are generally regressive, because they are more burdensome to low-income earners rather than their high-income counterparts.
Framework for Understanding Taxes
Слайд 51A progressive tax system is one in which the average tax rate
A progressive tax system is one in which the average tax rate
Progressive taxes are imposed in an attempt to reduce the tax incidence of people with a lower ability to pay, as such taxes shift the incidence increasingly to those with a higher ability-to-pay.
Example 19:
U.S. Tax Rates and Brackets, 2019
Framework for Understanding Taxes
Слайд 52Example 20:
Calculation of Tax Due on Taxable Income (progressive tax structure)
In
Example 20:
Calculation of Tax Due on Taxable Income (progressive tax structure)
In
If an individual has taxable income of €60,000, the first €15,000 is taxed at 23%; the next €13,000 is taxed at 27%, and so on. The amount of tax due on taxable income of €60,000 would be:
(€15,000 – €0) × 0.23 + (€28,000 – €15,000) × 0.27 + (€55,000 – €28,000) × 0.38 +
+ (€60,000 – €55,000) × 0.41 = €19,270
This would represent average tax rate of 32.12% (€19,270/ €60,000).
Framework for Understanding Taxes
Слайд 53A proportional tax system (a.k.a., flat tax system) is the one in
A proportional tax system (a.k.a., flat tax system) is the one in
The amount of the tax is in proportion to the amount subject to taxation, so that the marginal tax rate is equal to the average tax rate.
Proponents of proportional taxes believe they stimulate the economy by encouraging people to work more because there's no tax penalty for earning more.
They also believe that businesses are likely to spend and invest more under a flat tax system, thus stimulating the economy.
Example 21:
Proportional Tax Rate System
In a proportional tax system, all taxpayers are required to pay the same percentage of their income in taxes. For example, if the rate is set at 20%, a taxpayer earning $10,000 pays €2,000 and a taxpayer earning €50,000 pays €10,000. Similarly, a person earning €1 million would pay €200,000.
Framework for Understanding Taxes
Слайд 54Important Principles and Concepts in Tax Law
Most tax systems have developed around
Important Principles and Concepts in Tax Law
Most tax systems have developed around
Ability-to-Pay Principle
Under the ability-to-pay principle, the tax is based on what a taxpayer can
afford to pay.
One concept that results from this is that taxpayers are generally taxed on their net incomes.
Example 22:
Ability-to-Pay Principle
X and Y firms each have sales revenues of €500,000. Expenses for the two firms are €100,000 and €300,000, respectively. Firm X will pay more taxes, because it has greater net income and cash flows, and thus can afford to pay more.
Framework for Understanding Taxes
Слайд 55Entity Principle
Under the entity principle, an entity (such as a corporation)
Entity Principle
Under the entity principle, an entity (such as a corporation)
As such, the operations, record keeping, and taxable incomes of the entity and its owners (or affiliates) are separate.
Example 23:
Entity Principle
An entrepreneur forms a corporation that develops and sells the entrepreneur’s software products. During the year, the corporation has $200,000 in revenue and $50,000 in expenses. The entrepreneur also has a salary of $100,000.
The corporation will file a corporate tax return showing $50,000 in taxable income, and the entrepreneur will file an individual tax return showing $100,000 of income.
Framework for Understanding Taxes
Слайд 56Arm’s Length Principle
The condition or the fact that the parties to
Arm’s Length Principle
The condition or the fact that the parties to
Arm’s Length Transaction
A business deal in which the buyers and sellers act independently and do not have any relationship to each other. The concept of an arm's length transaction assures that both parties in the deal are acting in their own self-interest and are not subject to any pressure from the other party.
Note: Deals between family members or companies with related shareholders are usually not considered arm's length transactions.
Tax laws throughout the world are designed to treat the results of a transaction differently when parties are dealing at arm's length and when they are not.
e.g., if the sale of a house between father and son is taxable, tax authorities may require the seller to pay taxes on the gain he would have realized had he been selling to a neutral third party. They would disregard the actual price paid by the son.
Framework for Understanding Taxes
Слайд 57Example 24:
Arm’s Length Principle
Assume that in Example 23 the corporation pays its
Example 24:
Arm’s Length Principle
Assume that in Example 23 the corporation pays its
Suppose that a reasonable salary for a president of a small software company is $100,000.
The effect of the salary is to reduce the corporation’s taxable income to zero, so that it does not have to pay any taxes. While salaries in such closely held corporations are deductible in general, in this case the arm’s length test is not met.
As a result, only $100,000 (i.e., the reasonable portion) of the salary will be deductible by the corporation. The remaining $150,000 will be considered a dividend.
Arm's Length vs. Arm-in-Arm Transactions
In determining whether the arm’s length rule is likely to be violated with regard to expenses and losses, tax authorities look to see if the transaction is between related taxpayers.
Related taxpayers generally include individuals related by blood and marriage, and business entities owned more than 50% by a single entity or individual.
Framework for Understanding Taxes
Слайд 58Example 25:
Arm’s Length Test
Assume that an entrepreneur sells an asset to his
Example 25:
Arm’s Length Test
Assume that an entrepreneur sells an asset to his
Since the loss is not between related taxpayers, it may be considered arm’s length.
In applying the ownership test, constructive ownership is considered. That is, indirect ownership and chained ownership are considered.
Example 26:
Arm’s Length Test
Assume the same facts as Example 25, except that the other 51% of the stock is owned by Z Corporation, which is owned 100% by the entrepreneur.
By the rules of attribution and constructive ownership, the entrepreneur is considered to own 100% of the stock: by direct ownership in the first corporation, plus the stock owned by the Z Corporation.
Thus, the transaction is not arm’s length, and none of the loss would be deductible.
Framework for Understanding Taxes
Слайд 59Arm’s Length Principle: Business Expenses
Ordinary and necessary business expenses are deductible only
Arm’s Length Principle: Business Expenses
Ordinary and necessary business expenses are deductible only
Tax authorities have interpreted this requirement to mean that an expenditure is not reasonable when it is extravagant or exorbitant.
If the expenditure is extravagant in amount, it may be presumed that the excess amount is spent for personal rather than business reasons and, therefore, is not deductible.
Generally, tax authorities test for extravagance by comparing the amount of the expense to a market price or an arm’s length amount.
If the amount of the expense is within the range of amounts typically charged in the market by unrelated persons, the amount is considered to be reasonable.
Framework for Understanding Taxes
Слайд 60Example 27:
Business Deductions
Assume John hired four part-time employees and paid them $10
Example 27:
Business Deductions
Assume John hired four part-time employees and paid them $10
When things finally slowed down in late fall, John released his four part-time employees. John paid a total of $22,000 in compensation to the four employees.
He still needed some extra help now and then, so he hired his brother, Devin, on a part-time basis. Devin performed the same duties as the prior part-time employees (his quality of work was about the same). However, John paid Devin $25 per hour because Devin is a college student and John wanted to provide some additional support for Devin’s education.
At year-end, Devin had worked a total of 100 hours and received $2,500 from John.
Question:
What amount can John deduct for the compensation he paid to his employees?
Answer:
$23,000. John can deduct the entire $22,000 paid to the four part-time employees. However, he can only deduct $10 an hour for Devin’s compensation because the extra $15 per hour John paid Devin is unreasonable in amount. Hence, John can deduct a total of $23,000 for compensation expense this year [$22,000 + ($10 × 100)].
Framework for Understanding Taxes
Слайд 61All-Inclusive Income Principle
This principle basically means that if some simple tests
All-Inclusive Income Principle
This principle basically means that if some simple tests
The tests are as follows (each test must be met if an item is considered to be income):
Does it seem like income?
This test is meant to eliminate things that cannot be income.
Is there a transaction with another entity?
This test is the realization principle from accounting; that is, for income to be recognized, there must be a measurable transaction with another entity.
Framework for Understanding Taxes
For example, making an expenditure cannot generate income.
Слайд 62Example 28:
Realization Principle
A corporation owns two assets that have gone up in
Example 28:
Realization Principle
A corporation owns two assets that have gone up in
It sells the stock for its fair market value, but not the land.
Income is recognized only on the stock; there has been no realization on the land.
Is there an increase in wealth?
This test means that unless there is a change in net wealth, no income will be recognized. This eliminates a number of transactions from taxation.
Example 29:
Increase-in-wealth test
A corporation borrows $5 million from a bank, issues $1 million in common stock, and floats a bond issue for which it receives $10 million. Although each of these transactions involves cash inflows and transactions with other entities, there is no change in net wealth. This because for each of the three cash inflows, there is an offsetting increase in liabilities (or equity) payable.
Framework for Understanding Taxes
Слайд 63Business Purpose Concept
Relates to tax deductions.
Here, business expenses are deductible only if
Business Purpose Concept
Relates to tax deductions.
Here, business expenses are deductible only if
Example 30:
Business Purpose Test
An entrepreneur owns 100% of the stock of her corporation. She has the corporation buy an aircraft to facilitate any out-of-town business trips she might make. The entrepreneur, who also happens to enjoy flying as a hobby, rarely makes out-of-town business trips.
Since the plane will not really help the business, and there is a tax-avoidance motive (the plane would generate tax-depreciation deductions), there is no business purpose to the aircraft. Accordingly, any expenses related to the aircraft, including depreciation, are nondeductible.
Framework for Understanding Taxes
Слайд 64Tax-Benefit Rule
Under the tax-benefit rule, if a taxpayer receives a refund of
Tax-Benefit Rule
Under the tax-benefit rule, if a taxpayer receives a refund of
Example 31:
Tax-Benefit Rule
A company pays a consulting firm $100,000 for consulting services in one year. Because this is a normal business expense, the corporation takes a tax deduction for $100,000.
Early the next year, the consulting firm realizes it has made a billing mistake and refunds $20,000 of the fees.
The $20,000 is taxable income to the corporation in second year because it received a tax benefit in the prior year.
Framework for Understanding Taxes
Слайд 65Substance over Form Doctrine
Under the doctrine of substance over form, even when
Substance over Form Doctrine
Under the doctrine of substance over form, even when
Example 32:
Substance over Form Doctrine
An entrepreneur is the sole stockholder of his corporation. The corporation never pays dividends to the entrepreneur, and instead, each year it pays out 100% of the corporation’s net income as a salary to the entrepreneur (who also serves as company’s chief executive officer).
The doctrine of substance over form empowers tax authorities to tax at least part of the salary as if it were a dividend.
Framework for Understanding Taxes
Слайд 66Pay-As-You-Earn Concept (PAYE)
Taxpayers must pay part of their estimated annual tax liability
Pay-As-You-Earn Concept (PAYE)
Taxpayers must pay part of their estimated annual tax liability
For individuals, the most common example is income tax withholding.
Typically, withholding is required to be done by the employer of someone else, taking the tax payment funds out of the employee or contractor's salary or wages. The withheld taxes are then paid by the employer to the government body that requires payment, and applied to the account of the employee, if applicable.
This ensures the taxes will be paid first and will be paid on time, rather than risk the possibility that the tax-payer might default at the time when tax falls due.
Note:
In most countries, amounts withheld are determined by employers but subject to government review.
Framework for Understanding Taxes
Слайд 67Taxation of Gains and Losses on Property Sale
In virtually every tax jurisdiction,
Taxation of Gains and Losses on Property Sale
In virtually every tax jurisdiction,
Gain or loss is computed as
The adjusted basis of the property given is computed as
Framework for Understanding Taxes
Original basis +
Capital improvements −
Accumulated depreciation −
Other recoveries of investments (such as write-offs for casualty losses)
= Adjusted basis
Amount realized (the value of what is received)
− Adjusted basis of property given
= Gain or loss
The original basis usually is the original purchase price.
Capital improvements are additions that have an economic life beyond one year.
Accumulated depreciation applies only in the case of an asset used in business (see ex.).
Слайд 68Example 33:
Calculation of Gain / Loss
A corporation buys a factory building for
Example 33:
Calculation of Gain / Loss
A corporation buys a factory building for
Framework for Understanding Taxes
Слайд 69Chapter 3: PERSONAL INCOME TAX
Definition of Personal Income Tax
According to OECD, tax
Chapter 3: PERSONAL INCOME TAX
Definition of Personal Income Tax
According to OECD, tax
Throughout its history it is the tax that generates and has generated the most revenue for governments of the developed countries.
Personal income tax calculations as well as personal income tax rates may vary significantly depending on a tax jurisdiction.
Taxation rates may vary by type or characteristics of the taxpayer.
Individuals are often taxed at different rates than corporations. Individuals include only human beings.
Residents are generally taxed differently from non-residents.
Слайд 70Example 34:
Personal Income Tax Calculation (U.S. example)
Resident alien husband and wife with
Example 34:
Personal Income Tax Calculation (U.S. example)
Resident alien husband and wife with
Personal Income Tax Calculation Examples
Taxpayer’s income from salary and interest ($144, 100) is taxed at ordinary tax rates, see Schedule Y-1, Appendix 1. Here, taxpayer is in 22% tax bracket
Слайд 71The calculation of personal income taxes due (or refund) is based on
The calculation of personal income taxes due (or refund) is based on
Personal Income Tax Calculation Examples
Gross income
Minus: For AGI (above the line) deductions
Equals: Adjusted gross income (AGI)
Minus: From AGI (below the line) deductions:
(1) Greater of
(a) Standard deduction or
(b) Itemized deductions and
(2) Deduction for qualified business income
Equals: Taxable income
Times: Tax rates
Equals: Income tax liability
Plus: Other taxes
Equals: Total tax
Minus: Tax Credits
Minus: Tax Prepayments
Equals: Taxes due or (refund)
Source: Spilker, Ayers: Taxation of Individuals and Business Entities, McGraw-Hill, 2019 Edition
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
Слайд 72Explanations:
Gross income may include:
income from a job,
business income,
retirement income,
interest
Explanations:
Gross income may include:
income from a job,
business income,
retirement income,
interest
dividend income, and
capital gains from selling investments.
One type of income may be taxed at a different rate than another type of income depending on whether income is ordinary or capital.
Note: Examples of ordinary income are compensation for services, business income, retirement income. Ordinary income (loss) is taxed at ordinary tax rates (also depending on the family status), see App.1 (next slide).
Examples of capital income are gains and losses on the disposition or sale of capital assets.
If the gain is a long-term capital gain, it is generally taxed at a 15% tax rate (taxed at 20% for high-income taxpayers and 0% for low-income taxpayers).
If the gain is a short-term capital gain, the gain is taxed at ordinary income rates.
Personal Income Tax Calculation Examples
Based on the all-inclusive income principle. Under this principle, gross income generally includes all realized income from whatever source derived.
Realized income is income generated in a transaction with a second party in which there is a measurable change in property rights between parties (for example, appreciation in a stock investment would not represent realized income unless the taxpayer sold the stock).
1
Слайд 73Appendix 1
Source: Spilker, Ayers: Taxation of Individuals and Business Entities, McGraw-Hill, 2019
Appendix 1
Source: Spilker, Ayers: Taxation of Individuals and Business Entities, McGraw-Hill, 2019
Слайд 74Exclusions and Deferrals
Certain tax provisions allow taxpayers to permanently exclude specific types
Exclusions and Deferrals
Certain tax provisions allow taxpayers to permanently exclude specific types
Examples of exclusions:
Interest income from municipal bonds
Gifts and inheritance
Gain on sale of personal residence
Examples of deferrals:
Installment sale
Personal Income Tax Calculation Examples
Слайд 75Adjusted Gross Income (AGI)
It can be shown that
Some common For AGI
Adjusted Gross Income (AGI)
It can be shown that
Some common For AGI
Contribution to individual retirement account (IRA)
Health insurance deduction for self-employed taxpayers
Rental expenses
Capital losses (net losses limited to $3,000 for the year)
Personal Income Tax Calculation Examples
Gross Income
– For AGI Deductions
= AGI
2
Слайд 76From AGI Deductions
After calculating AGI, the taxpayer can then apply:
standard deductions to
From AGI Deductions
After calculating AGI, the taxpayer can then apply:
standard deductions to
itemized deductions, which can be better for the taxpayer in some situations.
Standardized Deduction
A fixed amount which varies by taxpayer filing status:
Personal Income Tax Calculation Examples
Every year the government indexes this deduction for
inflation.
See how the standard deduction of $24,400 is applied in Example 34.
3
Слайд 77Itemized Deduction
An expenditure on eligible products, services, or contributions that can be
Itemized Deduction
An expenditure on eligible products, services, or contributions that can be
Primary categories of itemized deductions are:
Medical and dental expenses
Taxes, e.g., state and local income taxes, sales taxes, real estate taxes, personal property taxes, and other taxes (an aggregate $10,000 deduction limitation applies to taxes).
Interest expense (mortgage and investment interest expense)
Gifts to charity
Deduction for Qualified Business Income
This deduction applies to individuals with qualified business income (QBI) from flow-through entities, including partnerships, S corporations, or sole proprietorships. This is a deduction for individuals not for business entities.
In general, a taxpayer can deduct 20% of the amount of QBI allocated to them from the entity, subject to certain limitations.
Personal Income Tax Calculation Examples
Note: Taxpayers generally deduct the higher of the standard deduction or itemized deductions.
Слайд 78Tax Rates
After determining taxable income, taxpayers can generally calculate their regular
Tax Rates
After determining taxable income, taxpayers can generally calculate their regular
However, as shown above, certain types of income included in taxable income are taxed at rates different from those in tax rate schedules (e.g., 15% tax applicable to capital gains, see. Ex.34).
Other Taxes
In addition to the individual income tax, individuals may also be required to pay other taxes such as the alternative minimum tax (AMT) or self-employment taxes. These taxes are imposed on tax bases other than the individual’s regular taxable income.
Tax Credits
These may include the child tax credit, the child and dependent care credit, the lifetime learning credit etc.
Personal Income Tax Calculation Examples
4
5
6
Note: Unlike deductions, which reduce taxable income, tax credits directly reduce taxes payable.
Слайд 79Tax Prepayments
These include:
withholdings, or income taxes withheld from the taxpayer’s
Tax Prepayments
These include:
withholdings, or income taxes withheld from the taxpayer’s
estimated tax payments the taxpayer makes for the year (paid directly to the IRS), and
tax that the taxpayer overpaid on the prior-year tax return that the taxpayer elects to apply as an estimated payment for the current tax year instead of receiving as a refund.
Personal Income Tax Calculation Examples
7
Note: If tax prepayments exceed the total tax after subtracting credits, the taxpayer receives a tax refund for the difference.
If tax prepayments are less than the total tax after credits, the taxpayer owes additional tax and potentially a penalty for the underpayment.
Слайд 80Example 35:
Personal Income Tax Calculation (UK example)
In 2017-18, Kenneth (who is not
Example 35:
Personal Income Tax Calculation (UK example)
In 2017-18, Kenneth (who is not
Personal Income Tax Calculation Examples
Слайд 81A typical structure of an income tax computation for year 2017-18 may
A typical structure of an income tax computation for year 2017-18 may
Personal Income Tax Calculation Examples
Total income
Less: Tax reliefs
Equals: Net income
Less: Personal allowance
Equals: Taxable income
Times: Tax rates
Less: Tax reductions
Equals: Tax borne
Add: Tax withheld on payments
Equals: Total liability for the year
Less: Tax paid by deduction at source
Equals: Tax payable
Source: Alan Melville: Taxation, Finance Act 2017, Pearson, 23rd Edition, 2018
1
2
3
4
5
6
Слайд 82Explanations:
Total income may include:
Employment income,
Pensions,
Social security income,
Trading income,
Property
Explanations:
Total income may include:
Employment income,
Pensions,
Social security income,
Trading income,
Property
Interest,
Dividends,
Miscellaneous income
Personal Income Tax Calculation Examples
Taxpayer's "total income" for the year is calculated by adding together income from all sources, including the pre-tax equivalent of any income from which tax has been deducted at source but excluding income which is exempt from income tax.
Certain types of income are taxed at source, which means that basic rate income tax is deducted from the income before the taxpayer receives it.
In tax year 2017 -18, the main types of income normally received net of basic rate tax are:
debenture and other loan interest;
interest on UK government securities (if taxpayer applies to receive this interest with tax deducted at source;
income element of a purchased life annuity;
patent royalty.
1
Note:
To calculate a taxpayer's income tax liability it is necessary to bring together all of the taxpayer's income into a single computation. The gross equivalent of any income received net of income tax must be included in the computation.
Note: Certain types of income are specifically exempt from income tax
Слайд 83Savings Income and Non-Savings Income
Tax liability on a taxpayer's "savings income"
Savings Income and Non-Savings Income
Tax liability on a taxpayer's "savings income"
Common categories of savings income are:
(a) interest received from banks, building societies and NS&I, plus interest received on gilt-edged securities and corporate bonds (e.g. debentures and loan stocks);
(b) income element of purchased life annuities (other than annuities from registered pension schemes, which are treated as non-savings income)
(c) certain foreign income.
Common categories of non-savings income are:
(a) income from employment and pensions;
(b) profits of trades, professions and vocations;
(c) income from property letting.
Personal Income Tax Calculation Examples
Note: Savings income does not include dividends received, which are treated in accordance with dividend income taxation principles.
Слайд 84Tax reliefs may include:
Certain payments made by the taxpayer (e.g., eligible interest
Tax reliefs may include:
Certain payments made by the taxpayer (e.g., eligible interest
Note: Most of the payments which are deductible from total income are made gross (without deduction of income tax)
Certain loss reliefs (e.g. trading losses) and
Relief for certain pension contributions
Personal allowance (PA)
The allowance is deducted from taxpayer’s income when computing the tax liability. The basic PA for 2017-2018 is £11,500 (see how it is applied in Ex. 35) but this is reduced (possibly to zero) if the taxpayer has income exceeding £100,000.
Note: Subject to certain conditions, an individual may elect to transfer part of his / her PA to a spouse or to a civil partner. The transferable amount is 10% of the basic PA for the year (i.e., £1,150 in 2017-18). This amount is called marriage allowance.
Personal Income Tax Calculation Examples
2
3
Слайд 85Tax rates
Income tax is charged on the taxable income, using the tax
Tax rates
Income tax is charged on the taxable income, using the tax
The amount of tax calculated in this way is then subject to a number of adjustments.
Savings income and dividend income are treated specially.
Personal Income Tax Calculation Examples
4
Слайд 86Tax Treatment of Savings Income
Savings income which falls into the first £5,000
Tax Treatment of Savings Income
Savings income which falls into the first £5,000
If a taxpayer has both savings income and non-savings income, it is necessary to split taxable income between these two categories before the tax liability can be calculated.
Note: Basic rate band is made available to non-savings income in priority to savings income.
The figure of £5,000 (for 2017-18) is known as the starting rate limit for savings.
Personal Income Tax Calculation Examples
Слайд 87Personal Savings Allowance (PSA)
Taxpayers may be entitled to a PSA of up
Personal Savings Allowance (PSA)
Taxpayers may be entitled to a PSA of up
In general, this means that the first £1,000 of savings income included in taxable income is taxed at the savings nil rate of 0%.
However, the PSA is lower than £1,000 in some cases:
Personal Income Tax Calculation Examples
Note: Figures are based on tax year 2017-2018
Слайд 88Example 36:
Personal Income Tax Calculation (UK example)
In 2017-18, Robert has business profits
Example 36:
Personal Income Tax Calculation (UK example)
In 2017-18, Robert has business profits
Personal Income Tax Calculation Examples
Taxable income includes non-savings income of more than £5,000. Therefore the
starting rate for savings is not available.
Taxable income does not exceed £33,500, so the PSA is £1,000.
Savings income of £1,000 is taxed at the savings nil rate.
The remaining £250 is taxed at basic rate.
Source: Alan Melville: Taxation, Finance Act 2017, Pearson, 23rd Edition, 2018
Слайд 89Example 37:
Personal Income Tax Calculation (UK example)
In 2017-18, Roberta has rental income
Example 37:
Personal Income Tax Calculation (UK example)
In 2017-18, Roberta has rental income
Personal Income Tax Calculation Examples
Non-savings income occupies £4,200 of the basic rate band. This allows £800 (£5,000 - £4,200) of savings income to be taxed at the starting rate of 0%.
Taxable income does not exceed £33,500, so the PSA is £1,000.
The remaining £300 of savings income
(£1,100 - £800) does not exceed £1,000, so this is taxed at the savings nil rate.
Source: Alan Melville: Taxation, Finance Act 2017, Pearson, 23rd Edition, 2018
Слайд 90Example 38:
In 2017-18, Philip (who is not a Scottish taxpayer) has business
Example 38:
In 2017-18, Philip (who is not a Scottish taxpayer) has business
Personal Income Tax Calculation Examples
Non-savings income occupies the whole of the basic band so the starting rate for savings is not available.
Taxable income exceeds £33,500, so the PSA is £nil.
The whole of the building society interest is taxed at the additional rate of 45%.
Source: Alan Melville: Taxation, Finance Act 2017, Pearson, 23rd Edition, 2018
Слайд 91Chapter 4: TAXATION OF INVESTMENT INCOME
Definition of Investment Income
Investment income is income
Chapter 4: TAXATION OF INVESTMENT INCOME
Definition of Investment Income
Investment income is income
e.g., interest earned on bank accounts and dividends received from stock owned by mutual fund holdings would all be considered investment income.
Investment Income and Taxes
Often, investment income undergoes different, and sometimes preferential, tax treatment, which varies by country and locality.
e.g., as of 2019, in the U.S., the top marginal tax rate on income was 37% (for amounts over $500,000 a year). Meanwhile, long-term capital gains and qualified dividend income were subject only to a maximum 20% tax, even if that amount exceeds a half-million dollars in a given year.
The associated tax rate is usually based on the form of investment producing the income and other aspects of an individual taxpayer’s situation.
Слайд 92Taxation of Interest and Dividends (US. Case)
For tax purposes, individual investors typically
Taxation of Interest and Dividends (US. Case)
For tax purposes, individual investors typically
Interest income is taxed at ordinary rates (i.e., as ordinary income). This means the interest is taxed at the taxpayer's top marginal tax rate (see App.1);
Some types of interest are fully taxable, while other forms are partially taxable.
Examples of interest income:
Interest from CDs, corporate bonds, and some types of government agency securities
Checking, savings, or other interest-bearing accounts
Dividend income is taxed annually and generally at lower capital gains rates.
Qualified dividends are taxed at a preferential rate: 0, 15, or 20%, depending on the taxpayer’s filing status and amount of taxable income. Qualified dividends are those paid by domestic or certain qualified foreign corporations, subject to certain restrictions.
Nonqualified dividends are not eligible for the reduced rate and are therefore taxed at ordinary rates.
Investment Income Taxation Examples
Слайд 93Example 39:
Assume Courtney (head of household filing status) decides to purchase dividend-paying
Example 39:
Assume Courtney (head of household filing status) decides to purchase dividend-paying
Question 1:
How much dividend income will Courtney report at the end of the first year if the dividend payments provide an 8% rate of return on her investments?
Answer:
At the end of the first year, Courtney will report $4,000 ($50,000 × 0.08) of dividend income from her investment in the Xerox stock and $4,000 ($50,000 × 0.08) of dividend income from her investment in the Coca-Cola stock, for a total of $8,000 of dividend income.
Investment Income Taxation Examples
Слайд 94Example 39:
Assume Courtney (head of household filing status) decides to purchase dividend-paying
Example 39:
Assume Courtney (head of household filing status) decides to purchase dividend-paying
Question 2:
Assume Courtney’s ordinary marginal tax rate is 32%. How much tax will Courtney owe on her dividend income if the dividends are nonqualified?
Answer:
Courtney will owe $2,560 ($8,000 × 32%) of tax if the dividends are nonqualified because
the income will be taxed at her ordinary income tax rate.
Investment Income Taxation Examples
Слайд 95Example 39:
Assume Courtney (head of household filing status) decides to purchase dividend-paying
Example 39:
Assume Courtney (head of household filing status) decides to purchase dividend-paying
Question 3:
What amount of tax will Courtney owe if the dividends are qualified? Assume Courtney’s tax rate on qualified dividends is 15%.
Answer:
Courtney will owe $1,200 ($8,000 × 15%) of tax if the dividends are qualified because qualified dividends are taxed at preferential rates.
Investment Income Taxation Examples
Слайд 96Taxation of Capital Gains and Losses (US. Case)
A capital gains tax is
Taxation of Capital Gains and Losses (US. Case)
A capital gains tax is
Example 40:
Let's assume you purchase 100 shares of XYZ Company for $1 per share. After three months, the share price increases to $5. This means the value of the investment has increased from $100 to $500, for a capital gain of $400.
The capital gain of $400 is subject to capital gains tax.
When a taxpayer sells a capital asset for more than its tax basis, he recognizes a capital gain;
However, if a taxpayer sells a capital asset for less than its tax basis, he recognizes a capital loss (to the extent the loss is deductible).
The tax basis of any asset is generally the taxpayer’s cost of acquiring the asset, including the initial purchase price and other costs incurred to purchase or improve the asset.
Investment Income Taxation Examples
Слайд 97FIFO method and Specific Identification Method
When taxpayers sell a capital asset, e.g.,
FIFO method and Specific Identification Method
When taxpayers sell a capital asset, e.g.,
By default, taxpayers are required to use the first-in, first-out (FIFO) method of determining the basis of the shares they sell.
However, if they track the basis of their stock, taxpayers can sell specific shares using the specific identification method to determine the basis of the shares they sell.
Taxpayers using the specific identification method can choose to sell their high-basis stock first, minimizing their gains or increasing their losses on stock dispositions.
Investment Income Taxation Examples
Слайд 98Example 41:
Assume Courtney sold 200 shares of Cisco stock at the current
Example 41:
Assume Courtney sold 200 shares of Cisco stock at the current
Question 1:
How much capital gain will Courtney recognize if she uses the FIFO method of computing the basis in the Cisco shares sold?
Answer:
$3,000.
$8,000 amount realized ($40 × 200) minus $5,000 FIFO basis ($25 × 200). As indicated
in the table above, under the FIFO (oldest first) method, the shares sold have a holding period of five years.
Investment Income Taxation Examples
Слайд 99Example 41:
Assume Courtney sold 200 shares of Cisco stock at the current
Example 41:
Assume Courtney sold 200 shares of Cisco stock at the current
Question 2:
How much capital gain will Courtney recognize if she uses the specific identification method of computing the basis in the shares sold to minimize the taxable gain on the sale?
Answer:
$1,600. $8,000 amount realized ($40 × 200) minus $6,400 ($32 × 200). To minimize her gain on the sale under the specific identification method, Courtney would choose to sell the 200 shares with the highest basis. As indicated in the table above, the shares with the higher basis are those acquired and held two years for $32 per share.
Investment Income Taxation Examples
Слайд 100Short-Term Capital Gains vs. Long-Term Capital Gains
Taxpayers selling capital assets they have
Short-Term Capital Gains vs. Long-Term Capital Gains
Taxpayers selling capital assets they have
Taxpayers selling capital assets they have held for more than a year recognize long-term capital gains or losses.
Short-term capital gains are taxed at ordinary rather than preferential rates.
In contrast, long-term capital gains are taxed at preferential rates.
Just like dividends, most long-term capital gains are taxed at either 0%, 15%, or 20%, depending on the taxpayer’s filing status and taxable income as shown in Exhibit.
Investment Income Taxation Examples
Source: Spilker, Ayers: Taxation of Individuals and Business Entities, McGraw-Hill, 2019 Edition
Слайд 101Tax Loss Harvesting
Many tax jurisdictions allow realized capital losses to offset realized
Tax Loss Harvesting
Many tax jurisdictions allow realized capital losses to offset realized
However, limitations are often placed on the amount of net losses that can be recognized or the type of income it can offset (e.g., short-term capital gains, long-term capital gains, or ordinary income).
Tax-loss harvesting is the practice or realizing a loss that offsets a gain or income – and thereby reducing the current year’s tax obligation.
This strategy is typically employed to limit the recognition of short-term capital gains. Short-term capital gains are generally taxed at a higher income tax rate than long-term capital gains.
For many investors, tax-loss harvesting is the most critical tool for reducing taxes.
Although tax-loss harvesting cannot restore an investor to the previous position, it can lessen the severity of the loss and result in significant tax savings.
Tax Loss Harvesting
Слайд 102Tax Loss Harvesting
Example 41a:
Eduardo has a €1,000,000 portfolio held in a taxable
Tax Loss Harvesting
Example 41a:
Eduardo has a €1,000,000 portfolio held in a taxable
Without making any further transactions, how much tax does Eduardo owe this year?
Solution:
Capital gain tax = 0.20 × €100,000 = €20,000.
How much tax will Eduardo owe this year if he sells the securities with the €60,000 loss?
Solution:
If Eduardo realizes €60,000 of losses, the net gain will be reduced to €40,000.
New capital gain tax = 0.20 × (€100,000 − €60,000) = €8,000.
Слайд 103Tax Loss Harvesting
Example 41a:
Eduardo has a €1,000,000 portfolio held in a taxable
Tax Loss Harvesting
Example 41a:
Eduardo has a €1,000,000 portfolio held in a taxable
How much tax will Eduardo save this year if he sells the securities with the €60,000 loss?
Solution:
Tax Savings = €20,000 − €8,000 = €12,000.
Слайд 104Tax Loss Harvesting
Tax Loss Harvesting
Слайд 105Taxation of Interest and Dividends (UK Case)
Interest received by a taxpayer is
Taxation of Interest and Dividends (UK Case)
Interest received by a taxpayer is
Interest ranks as savings income and so any interest which falls into the first £5,000 of taxable income (in 2017 -18) is taxed at the starting rate for saving s of 0%.
Basic rate taxpayers are also entitled to a personal savings allowance (PSA) of £1,000. This is reduced to £500 if taxable income exceeds the basic rate limit and to £nil if taxable income exceeds the higher rate limit. Interest which falls within the PSA in 2017-18 is taxed at the savings nil rate of 0%.
When preparing an income tax computation, the gross equivalent of any interest received net of tax should be included in total income. The tax suffered by deduction at source is then subtracted from the income tax liability when calculating the amount of tax payable for the year.
Note: Accrued interest is ignored when computing the amount of interest arising in a tax year.
Investment Income Taxation Examples
Слайд 106Example 42:
In 2017-18, Alfred had business profits of £15,870 and received net
Example 42:
In 2017-18, Alfred had business profits of £15,870 and received net
Investment Income Taxation Examples
Non-savings income occupies £4,370 of the basic rate band.
This allows £630 (£5,000 - £4,370) of savings income to be taxed at the starting rate of 0%.
Taxable income does not exceed £33,500, so the PSA is £1,000.
Accrued debenture interest of £950 is ignored
Слайд 107The income tax liability on a taxpayer's dividend income is calculated differently
The income tax liability on a taxpayer's dividend income is calculated differently
Dividends are treated as the top slice of taxable income, ranking above both non-savings and savings income.
(b) Dividends which fall into the basic rate band are generally taxed at the "dividend ordinary rate" of 7.5%.
Dividends which fall into the higher rate band are generally taxed at the "dividend upper rate" of 32.5%.
Any dividends which lie above the higher rate limit are generally taxed at the "dividend additional rate" of 38.1%.
(c) Taxpayers are entitled to a tax-free "dividend allowance" of £5,000 for the year, which means that the first £5,000 of dividends included in taxable income are taxed at the "dividend nil rate" of 0%. Unlike the personal savings allowance (see above, Chapter 3) which is reduced for higher-rate and additional -rate taxpayers, the dividend allowance is £5,000 in all cases.
Investment Income Taxation Examples
Слайд 108Example 43:
In tax year 2017-18, Christopher has rental income of £24,590. He
Example 43:
In tax year 2017-18, Christopher has rental income of £24,590. He
Investment Income Taxation Examples
Taxable income includes non-savings income of more than £5,000. Therefore the starting rate for savings is not available.
Taxable income exceeds the higher rate limit so the PSA is £nil. The whole of the bank interest is taxed at the basic rate of 20%.
Слайд 109Example 43:
In tax year 2017-18, Christopher has rental income of £24,590. He
Example 43:
In tax year 2017-18, Christopher has rental income of £24,590. He
Investment Income Taxation Examples
The first £5,000 of the dividends is taxed at the nil rate.
There is now
£ 2,860 of the basic rate band remaining (£33,500 – £24,590 – £1,050 – £5,000) and therefore the next £2,860 of the dividends is taxed at the dividend ordinary rate of 7.5%.
Слайд 110Example 43:
In tax year 2017-18, Christopher has rental income of £24,590. He
Example 43:
In tax year 2017-18, Christopher has rental income of £24,590. He
Investment Income Taxation Examples
Dividends of £116,500 which fall into the higher rate band are taxed at the dividend upper rate of 32.5%
and the final £79,740 of the dividends is taxed at the dividend additional rate of 38.1%.
Слайд 111Capital Gains Tax (UK Case)
For tax year 2017-18, there are two main
Capital Gains Tax (UK Case)
For tax year 2017-18, there are two main
the standard rate of 10% and
the higher rate of 20%.
Tax rates which apply to gains arising on the disposal of residential property (to the extent that these gains are not eligible for principal private residence relief) are 18% and 28%.
Furthermore, a special rate of 10% applies to gains which qualify for "entrepreneurs' relief" (ER). In general terms, gains may qualify for ER if they arise on the disposal of a business.
Investment Income Taxation Examples
Слайд 112Capital Gains Tax: Basis of Assessment
A person's CGT liability for a tax
Capital Gains Tax: Basis of Assessment
A person's CGT liability for a tax
No liability to CGT arises until an asset is disposed of, so the mere fact that an asset has appreciated in value will not of itself trigger a CGT liability. The amount on which CGT is payable is calculated as follows:
The chargeable gain or allowable loss arising on each disposal made during the tax year is calculated separately.
(b) If total gains exceed total losses, the losses are subtracted from the gains to give the taxpayer's "net gains" for the year.
If total losses exceed total gains, the gains are subtracted from the losses to give the "net losses" for the year.
Investment Income Taxation Examples
Note:
The main and most obvious instance of a chargeable disposal occurs when a chargeable asset (e.g., personal possessions, property, shares, business assets) is sold. However, the sale of an asset in the course of trade (i.e. the sale of trading stock or inventory) does not constitute a chargeable disposal since any gain arising on such a sale is taxed as a trading profit.
Слайд 113(c) If there are net gains for the year, these are reduced
(c) If there are net gains for the year, these are reduced
(d) Net gains are then further reduced by the amount of the "annual exemption" for the year (£11,300 for 2017 -18). The amount of any net gains which remain after the annual exemption has been deducted is the "taxable gains" figure for the year.
If net gains are too low to allow the whole of the annual exemption to be deducted, taxable gains for the year are £nil and the balance of the annual exemption is lost.
(e) If there are net losses for the year, taxable gains for that year are £nil and the whole of the annual exemption is lost. The net losses may then be carried forward for relief in future years (i.e., net capital losses are carried forward and set against the net gains of subsequent years).
Investment Income Taxation Examples
Слайд 114Example 44:
Four taxpayers each make three chargeable disposals during 2017-18.
Compute their
Example 44:
Four taxpayers each make three chargeable disposals during 2017-18.
Compute their
Taxpayer A has gains of £3,500, £4,100 and £5,950.
Solution:
Total gains are £13,550 and there are no losses. Net gains are £13,550. Subtracting the annual exemption of £11,300 gives taxable gains for the year of £2,250.
(b) Taxpayer B has gains of £5,700, £6,840 and a loss of £350.
Solution:
Total gains are £12,540. Total losses are £350 so net gains are £12,190. Subtracting the annual exemption of £11,300 gives taxable gains for the year of £890.
Investment Income Taxation Examples
Слайд 115Example 44:
Four taxpayers each make three chargeable disposals during 2017-18.
Compute their
Example 44:
Four taxpayers each make three chargeable disposals during 2017-18.
Compute their
(c) Taxpayer C has gains of £950 and £9,530 and a loss of £2,050.
Solution:
Total gains are £ 10,480 and total losses are £2,050. Net gains are £ 8,430. This is less than the annual exemption of £11,300, so taxable gains for the year are £nil. The unused part of the annual exemption (£2,870) is lost.
(d) Taxpayer D has a gain of £8,950 and losses of £9,500 and £800.
Solution:
Total gains are £8,950 and total losses are £10,300. Net losses are £1,350. Taxable gains for the year are £nil and the whole of the annual exemption is lost.
Investment Income Taxation Examples
Слайд 116Calculation of Capital Gains Tax Payable
CGT rates are applied to the taxable
Calculation of Capital Gains Tax Payable
CGT rates are applied to the taxable
Gains which qualify for ER are always taxed at the ER rate of 10%.
(b) If the individual's taxable income for the year (see previous notes) exceeds the basic rate limit, gains which do not qualify for ER are taxed at the higher rate of 20% (or 28% in the case of residential property gains).
(c) If taxable income does not exceed the basic rate limit, any unused part of the basic rate band is first absorbed by gains which qualify for ER.
Gains which do not qualify for ER are then normally taxed at the lower rate of 10% to the extent that they do not exceed any remaining part of the basic rate band and at 20% otherwise. But these rates are increased to 18% and 28% in the case of residential property gains.
The basic rate limit for 2017-18 is usually £33,500 (see previous notes).
Investment Income Taxation Examples
Слайд 117Example 45:
Calculate the amount of CGT payable for 2017-18 by each of
Example 45:
Calculate the amount of CGT payable for 2017-18 by each of
In each case, "taxable income" comprises the individual's total income, less reliefs which
may be deducted from total income and less the personal allowance.
A: Taxable income exceeds the basic rate limit (£33,500), so the "other" gains are taxed at 20%.
Net gains are reduced by the annual exemption (£11,300), so CGT payable is (£12,500 – £11,300) x 20% = £240.
Investment Income Taxation Examples
Слайд 118Example 45:
Calculate the amount of CGT payable for 2017-18 by each of
Example 45:
Calculate the amount of CGT payable for 2017-18 by each of
In each case, "taxable income" comprises the individual's total income, less reliefs which
may be deducted from total income and less the personal allowance.
B: Taxable income is not relevant since gains which qualify for ER are always taxed at
10%. CGT payable is (£12,500 – £11,300) x 10% = £120.
Investment Income Taxation Examples
Слайд 119Example 45:
Calculate the amount of CGT payable for 2017-18 by each of
Example 45:
Calculate the amount of CGT payable for 2017-18 by each of
In each case, "taxable income" comprises the individual's total income, less reliefs which
may be deducted from total income and less the personal allowance.
C: The tax liability is minimized if the annual exemption is set against the residential property gains, since these are taxed at higher rates than gains which qualify for ER.
Taxable income exceeds the basic rate limit, so CGT payable is (£32,800 x 10%) +
((£15,700 – £11,300) x 28%) = £4,512.
Investment Income Taxation Examples
Слайд 120Example 45:
Calculate the amount of CGT payable for 2017-18 by each of
Example 45:
Calculate the amount of CGT payable for 2017-18 by each of
In each case, "taxable income" comprises the individual's total income, less reliefs which
may be deducted from total income and less the personal allowance.
D: To minimize the tax liability, the allowable losses of £1,000 are set against the "other" gains of £4,900. Similarly, the annual exemption (£11,300) is set first against these gains. The remaining £7,400 of the exemption must then be set against the gains which qualify for ER. CGT payable is (£27,600 – £7,400) x 10% = £2,020.
Investment Income Taxation Examples
Слайд 121Example 45:
Calculate the amount of CGT payable for 2017-18 by each of
Example 45:
Calculate the amount of CGT payable for 2017-18 by each of
In each case, "taxable income" comprises the individual's total income, less reliefs which
may be deducted from total income and less the personal allowance.
E: After deducting the annual exemption, taxable gains are £400 and these consist of residential property gains.
The unused part of the basic rate band is £2,710 (£33,500 – £30,790). This exceeds the taxable gains so CGT payable is (£400 x 18%) = £72.
Investment Income Taxation Examples
Слайд 122Example 45:
Calculate the amount of CGT payable for 2017-18 by each of
Example 45:
Calculate the amount of CGT payable for 2017-18 by each of
In each case, "taxable income" comprises the individual's total income, less reliefs which
may be deducted from total income and less the personal allowance.
F: Taxable gains are £8,600 (£20,300 – £400 – £11,300) and these consists of "other" gains. The unused part of the basic rate band is £1,800 (£33,500 – £31,700).
So the CGT payable is (£1,800 x 10%) + (£6,800 x 20%) = £1,540.
Investment Income Taxation Examples
Слайд 123Example 45:
Calculate the amount of CGT payable for 2017-18 by each of
Example 45:
Calculate the amount of CGT payable for 2017-18 by each of
In each case, "taxable income" comprises the individual's total income, less reliefs which
may be deducted from total income and less the personal allowance.
G: The tax liability is minimized if the losses of £2,200 and the annual exemption of £11,300 are both set against the residential property gains, leaving £3,500 of these gains remaining (£17,000 – £2,200 – £11,300). The unused part of the basic rate band is £10,400 (£33,500 – £23,100) and ER gains absorb £4,000 of this.
Investment Income Taxation Examples
Слайд 124Example 45:
Calculate the amount of CGT payable for 2017-18 by each of
Example 45:
Calculate the amount of CGT payable for 2017-18 by each of
In each case, "taxable income" comprises the individual's total income, less reliefs which
may be deducted from total income and less the personal allowance.
If the basic rate band is allocated next to residential property gains, CGT payable is (£4,000 x 10%) + (£3,500 x 18%) + (£2,900 x 10%) + (£5,600 x 20%) = £2,440.
If the basic rate band is allocated next to the "other" gains instead, CGT payable is
(£4,000 x 10%) + (£6,400 x 10%) + (£2,100 x 20%) + (£3,500 x 28%) = £2,440.
Investment Income Taxation Examples
Слайд 125Example 45:
Calculate the amount of CGT payable for 2017-18 by each of
Example 45:
Calculate the amount of CGT payable for 2017-18 by each of
In each case, "taxable income" comprises the individual's total income, less reliefs which
may be deducted from total income and less the personal allowance.
The tax liability is un affected by the allocation of the basic rate band and this will generally be the case in 2017 -18, since the gap between the 10% and 20% rates is the same as the gap between the 18% and 28% rates.
Investment Income Taxation Examples
Слайд 126Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns
After-Tax Accumulations and Returns for Taxable Accounts
Taxes
Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns
After-Tax Accumulations and Returns for Taxable Accounts
Taxes
Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns
The effect of taxes on investment returns depends on the following factors:
Tax rate
Return on investment
Frequency of payment of taxes
Слайд 127Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns
There are two types of methods of
Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns
There are two types of methods of
Accrual taxes on interest and dividends that are paid annually.
Deferred capital gain taxes.
1. Returns-Based Taxes: Accrual Taxes on Interest and Dividends
Accrual taxes are taxes that are levied and paid on a periodic basis, usually annually, as opposed to deferred taxes that are postponed until some future date.
When returns are subject to accrual taxes, the after-tax return is equal to the pretax return, r, multiplied by (1 − ti) where ti represents the tax rate applicable to investment income:
Assumption:
an investment with a return that is entirely taxed at a single uniform rate.
Слайд 128Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns
The amount of money accumulated for each
Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns
The amount of money accumulated for each
Example 46:
Assume that €100 are invested at 6% per annum for 10 years in an environment in which returns are taxed each year at a rate of 30%.
This will accumulate to be €100[1 + 0.06(1 − 0.30)]10 = €150.90.
Had returns not been taxed, this investment would have grown to
€100[1 + 0.06(1 − 0.00)]10 = €179.08,
a difference of €28.18.
Equation is a future value interest factor (FVIF) based on an after-tax return.
Слайд 129Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns
Tax Drag on Capital Accumulation
Tax drag is
Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns
Tax Drag on Capital Accumulation
Tax drag is
Tax drag can be expressed in currency units as follows:
Tax drag (€) = accumulated capital without tax – accumulated capital with tax
or in percentage terms:
Tax drag (%) = (accumulated capital without tax – accumulated capital with tax)
/ (accumulated capital without tax – initial investment)
Note: The denominator of the formula can also be seen as an investment gain, assuming t = 0%
Слайд 130Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns
Example 47:
John is determining the impact of
Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns
Example 47:
John is determining the impact of
Also he expects to earn 7% per year on his investment over a 20 year time horizon and has an initial portfolio of €100,000.
What is John’s expected wealth at the end of 20 years?
What proportion of potential investment gains were consumed by taxes?
Solution:
FV = €100,000 × FVIFi
= €100,000 × [1 + 0.07(1 – 0.20)]20
= €297,357.
2. Ignoring taxes, FV = €100,000 [1 + 0.07]20 = €386,968. The difference between this and the after tax amount accumulated from above is €89,611. The proportion of potential investment gains consumed by taxes was €89,611/€286,968 = 31.23% (tax drag (%)).
Слайд 131Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns
Implications of tax drag (assuming accrual taxation)
When
Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns
Implications of tax drag (assuming accrual taxation)
When
Tax drag is greater than the nominal tax rate.
Tax drag and investment time horizon (n) are positively correlated i.e. as the investment horizon (n) increases, tax drag increases, all else equal.
Tax drag and investment returns (r) are positively correlated i.e. as the investment return increases, tax drag increases, all else equal.
Investment return and time horizon have a multiplicative effect on the tax drag i.e.
Given investment returns, the longer the time horizon, the greater the tax drag.
Given investment time horizon, the higher the investment returns, the greater the tax drag.
Слайд 132Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns
2. Returns-Based Taxes: Deferred Capital Gains
Deferred capital
Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns
2. Returns-Based Taxes: Deferred Capital Gains
Deferred capital
Under deferred capital gain tax, investment grows tax free until assets are sold.
If the tax on an investment’s return is deferred until the end of its investment horizon, n, and taxed as a capital gain at the rate tcg, then the after-tax future accumulation for each unit of currency can be represented as follows:
Note:
The first term of equation represents the future accumulation if the entire sum (including the original basis) were subject to tax. The second term returns the tax of the untaxed cost (also known as cost basis or basis) associated with the initial investment.
Слайд 133Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns
Example 48:
Assume that €100 are invested at
Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns
Example 48:
Assume that €100 are invested at
This will accumulate to be €100[(1 + 0.06)10(1 − 0.30) + 0.30] = €155.36.
Notice that this sum is greater than the €150.90 accumulated in example 46, where returns are taxed annually at the same rate. This comparison illustrates the value of tax deferral.
Notice, as well, that the after-tax investment gain equals the pretax investment gain multiplied by one minus the tax rate. That is, €55.36 = €79.08 × (1 − 0.30).
Whereas the tax drag on after-tax accumulations subject to annual accrual taxes compounds over time, the tax drag from deferred capital gains is a fixed percentage regardless of the investment return or time horizon. In other words, when deferral is permitted, the proportion of potential investment growth consumed by taxes is always the same as the tax rate, 30% in this case.
Слайд 134Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns
Implications of tax drag (assuming taxes on
Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns
Implications of tax drag (assuming taxes on
Investments taxed on a deferred capital gain basis are more tax-efficient than investments with returns that are taxed annually.
Example 49:
Assume the same facts as in Example 47. John invests €100,000 at 7%.
However, the return comes in the form of deferred capital gains that are not taxed until the investment is sold in 20 years hence.
What is John’s expected wealth at the end of 20 years?
What proportion of potential investment gains were consumed by taxes?
Solution:
FV = €100,000 × FVIFcg
= €100,000 × [(1 + 0.07)20(1 – t) + t]
= €100,000 × [(1 + 0.07)20(1 – 0.20) + 0.20] = €329,575.
2. Ignoring taxes, FV = €100,000 [1 + 0.07]20 = €386,968. The difference between this and the after tax amount accumulated from above is €57,393. The proportion of potential investment gains consumed by taxes was €57,393/€286,968 = 20.0% (tax drag (%)).
This result compares favorably to the potential investment gains consumed by taxes in Example 47.
Слайд 135Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns
3. Wealth-Based Taxes
Some jurisdictions impose a wealth
Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns
3. Wealth-Based Taxes
Some jurisdictions impose a wealth
Often the wealth tax is restricted to real estate investments (e.g., Australia, Singapore, Belgium, Germany, and the United Kingdom). In other countries, it is levied on aggregate assets including financial assets above a certain threshold (e.g., Colombia).
If limited to real estate holdings, the wealth tax may be levied at the federal level or a municipal level.
In any case, the wealth tax rate tends to be much lower than capital gains or interest income rates because it applies to the entire capital base—i.e., principal and return—rather than just the return.
Слайд 136Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns
If wealth is taxed annually at a
Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns
If wealth is taxed annually at a
Example 50:
If wealth capital is taxed at 2%, then €100 invested at 6% for 10 years will grow to 100[(1.06)(1 − 0.02)]10 = €146.33.
Because the form of a wealth tax differs from the form of taxes on either investment returns or deferred capital gains, this figure is not comparable to examples 46 and 48.
This figure is substantially less than the pretax accumulation of €179.08, however. In other words, the 2% wealth tax consumed 41.4% of the investment growth that would have accrued over 10 years in the absence of a wealth tax (i.e., (€79.08 − €46.33)/€79.08).
Слайд 137Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns
Implications of tax drag (assuming tax on
Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns
Implications of tax drag (assuming tax on
Tax drag (%) is greater than the nominal tax rate
A wealth tax consumes a greater proportion of investment growth when returns are low.
When returns are flat or negative, a wealth tax effectively reduces principal.
Like the previous two types of taxes, however, the wealth tax consumes a greater share of investment growth as the investment horizon increases.
Слайд 138Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns
Example 51:
Olga lives in a country that
Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns
Example 51:
Olga lives in a country that
What is Olga’s expected wealth at the end of ten years?
What proportion of investment gains was consumed by taxes?
Solution:
FV = €400,000[(1.06)(1 − 0.01)]10 = €647,844.
Had the wealth tax not existed, FV = €400,000(1.06)10 = €716,339.
This sum represents a €316,339 investment gain compared to a €247,844 gain in the presence of the wealth tax. Therefore, the 1% wealth tax consumed 21.65% of the investment gain (i.e., (€316,339 − €247,844)/€316,339).
Слайд 139Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns
Blended Taxing Environments
In reality, investment portfolios are
Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns
Blended Taxing Environments
In reality, investment portfolios are
The different taxing schemes mentioned above can be integrated into a single framework in which:
a portion of a portfolio’s investment return is received in the form of dividends (pd) and taxed at a rate of td;
another portion is received in the form of interest income (pi) and taxed as such at a rate of ti;
and another portion is taxed as realized capital gain (pcg) at tcg.
The remainder of an investment’s return is unrealized capital gain, the tax on which is deferred until ultimately recognized at the end of the investment horizon.
These return proportions can be computed by simply dividing each income component by the total euro return.
Слайд 140Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns
It can be shown that:
Total realized tax
Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns
It can be shown that:
Total realized tax
So, the annual return after realized taxes can be expressed as
Note:
The equation does not take into account tax obligations arising from gains not yet realized.
where:
r = pre-tax overall return on portfolio;
p = proportion of total return from each source;
Слайд 141Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns
Example 52:
Michael has a balanced portfolio of
Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns
Example 52:
Michael has a balanced portfolio of
What percentage of Michael’s return is in the form of interest?
Solution:
pi = €400/€8,000 = 0.05 or 5%.
2. What percentage of Michael’s return is in the form of dividends?
Solution:
pd = €2,000/€8,000 = 0.25 or 25%.
Слайд 142Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns
Example 52:
Michael has a balanced portfolio of
Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns
Example 52:
Michael has a balanced portfolio of
What percentage of Michael’s return is in the form of realized capital gain?
Solution:
pcg = €3,600/€8,000 = 0.45 or 45%.
What percentage of Michael’s return is in the form of deferred capital gain?
Solution:
Unrealized gain = €8,000 − €400 − €2,000 − €3,600 = €2,000. Expressed as a percentage of return, €2,000/€8,000 = 0.25, or 25%.
The unrealized gain is the portion of investment appreciation that was not taxed as either interest, dividends, or realized capital gain.
Слайд 143Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns
Example 52:
Michael has a balanced portfolio of
Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns
Example 52:
Michael has a balanced portfolio of
5. What is the annual return after realized taxes?
Solution:
r* = r(1 – piti – pdtd – pcgtcg)
= 8%[1 – (0.05 × 0.35) – (0.25 × 0.15) – (0.45 × 0.15)]
= 7.02%
Слайд 144Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns
Example 52:
Michael has a balanced portfolio of
Effect of Taxes on Investment Returns
Example 52:
Michael has a balanced portfolio of
6. Assuming taxes are paid out of the investment account, what is the balance in the account at the end of the first year?
Solution:
After paying taxes there would be €107,020 in the account (€108,000 − €980). Note that this is consistent with the 7.02% return computed for the first question.
Слайд 145Chapter 5: CORPORATION TAX
Definition of Corporate Tax
Corporate tax (a.k.a. corporation tax) is
Chapter 5: CORPORATION TAX
Definition of Corporate Tax
Corporate tax (a.k.a. corporation tax) is
Partnerships are generally not taxed at the entity level.
Company income subject to tax is often determined much like taxable income for individual taxpayers. Generally, the tax is imposed on net profits.
In some jurisdictions, rules for taxing companies may differ significantly from rules for taxing individuals. Certain corporate acts, like reorganizations, may not be taxed. Some types of entities may be exempt from tax.
Countries may tax corporations on its net profit and may also tax shareholders when the corporation pays a dividend.
Слайд 146Corporate Tax Rates
International Corporate Tax Rates
Corporate tax rates vary widely by country,
Corporate Tax Rates
International Corporate Tax Rates
Corporate tax rates vary widely by country,
Corporate Tax Rates (%)
Source:
KPMG, 2019
Слайд 147The calculation of corporate income taxes due (or refund) is based on
The calculation of corporate income taxes due (or refund) is based on
Corporations compute gross income as do other types of business entities and individual taxpayers. In contrast to individual taxpayers, corporations do not calculate adjusted gross income (AGI). Like other businesses, corporations are allowed to deduct ordinary and necessary business expenditures. Unlike individual taxpayers, corporations treat all deductions as related to a trade or business. Corporations also do not receive a standard deduction.
Corporate Income Tax Calculation Examples
Gross income
Minus: Deductions
Equals: Taxable income
Times: Tax rates
Equals: Income tax liability
Plus: Other taxes
Equals: Total tax
Minus: Tax Credits
Minus: Tax Prepayments
Equals: Taxes due or (refund)
Source: Spilker, Ayers: Taxation of Individuals and Business Entities, McGraw-Hill, 2019 Edition
1
2
3
4
Слайд 148Explanations:
Gross income may include:
gross profit from inventory sales (sales minus cost of
Explanations:
Gross income may include:
gross profit from inventory sales (sales minus cost of
income from services provided to customers,
income from renting property to customers.
Corporate Income Tax Calculation Examples
Note:
In most respects, the rules for determining business gross income are the same as for determining gross income for individuals. Business gross income generally includes all income from whatever source derived.
1
Слайд 149Some common business deductions are:
Ordinary and necessary business expenses
Corporate Income Tax Calculation
Some common business deductions are:
Ordinary and necessary business expenses
Corporate Income Tax Calculation
2
Note:
Only reasonable amounts are allowed as business expense deductions (see example 27). Extravagant or excessive amounts are likely to be characterized by personal motives and are disallowed.
Слайд 150Some limitations on business deductions:
Capital expenditures (e.g., expenditures for tangible assets such
Some limitations on business deductions:
Capital expenditures (e.g., expenditures for tangible assets such
For tax purposes, businesses recover the cost of capitalized tangible assets (excluding land) through depreciation.
Businesses also capitalize the cost to create or acquire intangible assets such as patents, goodwill, start-up costs, and organizational expenditures. They recover the costs of capitalized intangible assets either through amortization (when the tax laws allow them to do so) or upon disposition of the assets.
Personal expenses (e.g., food, clothing etc. or family expenses) are generally not deductable.
Corporate Income Tax Calculation Examples
Слайд 151Business interest expense
Deduction for business interest expense is limited to the
Business interest expense
Deduction for business interest expense is limited to the
business interest income and
30% of the adjusted taxable income of the taxpayer for the taxable year.
Adjusted taxable income (ATI) is taxable income allocable to the business computed without interest income and before depreciation and interest expense deductions.
Disallowed business interest expense can be carried forward indefinitely.
Corporate Income Tax Calculation Examples
Слайд 152Computing corporate taxable income
To compute taxable income, most corporations begin with
Computing corporate taxable income
To compute taxable income, most corporations begin with
Book-Tax Differences
Many items of income and expense are accounted for differently for book and tax purposes. As a result, book-tax differences arise.
Each book–tax difference can be considered “unfavorable” or “favorable” depending on its effect on taxable income relative to book income.
Favorable book–tax differences decrease taxable income relative to book income.
Unfavorable book–tax differences increase taxable income relative to book income.
Corporate Income Tax Calculation Examples
3
Слайд 153In addition to the favorable/unfavorable distinction, book–tax differences can be categorized as
In addition to the favorable/unfavorable distinction, book–tax differences can be categorized as
• Permanent book–tax differences arise in one year and never reverse.
Businesses, including corporations, are allowed to exclude certain income items from gross income, and they are not allowed to deduct certain expenditures for tax purposes.
Because these income items are included in book income, and the expenditures are deducted for financial reporting purposes, they generate permanent book–tax differences.
Corporate Income Tax Calculation Examples
Слайд 154Some Common Permanent Book-Tax Differences
Corporate Income Tax Calculation Examples
Source: Spilker, Ayers: Taxation
Some Common Permanent Book-Tax Differences
Corporate Income Tax Calculation Examples
Source: Spilker, Ayers: Taxation
Слайд 155• Temporary book–tax differences arise in one year and reverse in a
• Temporary book–tax differences arise in one year and reverse in a
Corporations experience temporary book–tax differences because the accounting methods they apply to determine certain items of income and expense for financial reporting purposes differ from those they use for tax purposes.
Unlike permanent book–tax differences, temporary book–tax differences balance out over time, so corporations eventually recognize the same amount of income or deduction for the particular item.
Corporate Income Tax Calculation Examples
Слайд 156Some Common Temporary Book-Tax Differences
Corporate Income Tax Calculation Examples
*Note that each of
Some Common Temporary Book-Tax Differences
Corporate Income Tax Calculation Examples
*Note that each of
Слайд 157Corporate-Specific Deductions and Book-Tax Differences
Net Capital Losses
For corporations, all net capital gains
Corporate-Specific Deductions and Book-Tax Differences
Net Capital Losses
For corporations, all net capital gains
Unlike individuals, corporations cannot deduct net capital losses against ordinary income (individuals can deduct up to $3,000 of net capital losses in a year against ordinary income)
Corporations may not deduct net capital losses for tax purposes.
However, they may carry them back three years and forward five years to offset capital gains in those other years.
Corporate Income Tax Calculation Examples
Слайд 158Example 53: Book–Tax Reconciliation Template
Source: Spilker, Ayers: Taxation of Individuals and Business
Example 53: Book–Tax Reconciliation Template
Source: Spilker, Ayers: Taxation of Individuals and Business
In the example, $12,000 of the total interest income is interest income earned from municipal bonds, which is deducted for tax purposes
(favorable adjustment, permanent book-tax difference)
Note:
Numbers in the debit column are favorable book–tax adjustments while numbers in the credit column are unfavorable book–tax adjustments.
Слайд 159Example 53: Book–Tax Reconciliation Template
Capital losses of $28,000 are not deducted for
Example 53: Book–Tax Reconciliation Template
Capital losses of $28,000 are not deducted for
(unfavorable adjustment)
Слайд 160Example 53: Book–Tax Reconciliation Template
Initial estimated fair value of stock options is
Example 53: Book–Tax Reconciliation Template
Initial estimated fair value of stock options is
(unfavorable adjustment, permanent book-tax difference)
Слайд 161Example 53: Book–Tax Reconciliation Template
Temporary book-tax differences
Example 53: Book–Tax Reconciliation Template
Temporary book-tax differences
Слайд 162Example 53: Book–Tax Reconciliation Template
Business-related meal expenses of $28,000 are fully deductible
Example 53: Book–Tax Reconciliation Template
Business-related meal expenses of $28,000 are fully deductible
(unfavorable adjustment, permanent book-tax difference)
Слайд 163Example 53: Book–Tax Reconciliation Template
Corporations deduct federal income tax expense in determining
Example 53: Book–Tax Reconciliation Template
Corporations deduct federal income tax expense in determining
(permanent book-tax difference).
Note: *This number is used only for illustrative purposes.
Слайд 164Example 53: Book–Tax Reconciliation Template
Corporations are allowed a deduction for dividends received
Example 53: Book–Tax Reconciliation Template
Corporations are allowed a deduction for dividends received
The amount of the deduction depends on the corporation’s ownership in the distributing corporation. The deduction is 50% if the ownership is less than 20%; the deduction is 65% if the ownership is at
least 20% but less than 80%; and finally, the deduction is 100% if the ownership is 80% or more.
Слайд 165Corporate income tax liability:
When corporations calculate their taxable income, they compute their
Corporate income tax liability:
When corporations calculate their taxable income, they compute their
In Example 53, the taxable income is $5,621,700. Thus, the tax liability using a flat rate of 21% is $1,180,557, i.e. $5,621,700(0.21).
Corporate Income Tax Calculation Examples
4
Source: Spilker, Ayers: Taxation of Individuals and Business Entities, McGraw-Hill, 2019 Edition
Слайд 166Scope of Corporation Tax (U.K. case)
A company's taxable total profits include both
Scope of Corporation Tax (U.K. case)
A company's taxable total profits include both
The term "chargeable gains" is normally used in preference to "capital gains".
Main source of income for most companies is likely to be trading income. But a company may also have other sources of income.
These could include:
bank interest,
loan interest,
property income etc.
In general terms, a company's income is computed i n a broadly similar way to that of an individual.
Corporate Income Tax Calculation Examples
Слайд 167Calculation of company’s taxable total profits may be summarized as follows:
Corporate Income
Calculation of company’s taxable total profits may be summarized as follows:
Corporate Income
Source: Alan Melville: Taxation, Finance Act 2017, Pearson, 23rd Edition, 2018
1
Consists mainly of bank and building society interest and any other interest receivable by a company.
Слайд 168Calculation of company’s taxable total profits may be summarized as follows:
Corporate Income
Calculation of company’s taxable total profits may be summarized as follows:
Corporate Income
1
Capital gains on chargeable assets which consist of non-current assets such as land and buildings, plant and investments.
Non -chargeable assets include motor cars, chattels worth up to £6,000, gilts and qualifying corporate bonds.
Слайд 169Notes:
Trading income consists of company’s trading profit for an accounting period, as
Notes:
Trading income consists of company’s trading profit for an accounting period, as
The starting point for the calculation is the company's pre-tax profit. This figure is then adjusted by:
Excluding non-trading income and
adding back disallowed expenses.
Capital allowances claimed for each accounting period are then deducted.
Corporate Income Tax Calculation Examples
1
Слайд 170Example 54:
Calculation of a company’s trading income (UK case)
A company's income statement
Example 54:
Calculation of a company’s trading income (UK case)
A company's income statement
Notes:
1. Distribution costs are as follows:
Corporate Income Tax Calculation Examples
The other income of £24,000 consists of rents receivable.
Слайд 1712. Administrative expenses are as follows:
Corporate Income Tax Calculation Examples
Compute the company's
2. Administrative expenses are as follows:
Corporate Income Tax Calculation Examples
Compute the company's
Слайд 172Solution:
Corporate Income Tax Calculation Examples
Gift Aid donations are disallowed when computing trading
Solution:
Corporate Income Tax Calculation Examples
Gift Aid donations are disallowed when computing trading
Слайд 173Solution:
Corporate Income Tax Calculation Examples
Losses caused by the dishonesty of a director
Solution:
Corporate Income Tax Calculation Examples
Losses caused by the dishonesty of a director
Слайд 174Computation of Corporation Tax Liability (U.K. case)
Given a company's taxable total profits
Computation of Corporation Tax Liability (U.K. case)
Given a company's taxable total profits
Corporation tax liability = TTP × corporation tax rate
As from 1 April 2015, there is a single rate of corporation tax for each financial year. Main rates for FY2015 through to FY2020 are currently set as follows:
Corporate Income Tax Calculation Examples
Source: Alan Melville: Taxation, Finance Act 2017, Pearson, 23rd Edition, 2018
Слайд 175Chapter 6: INDIRECT TAXES: VALUE-ADDED TAX
Definition of Value Added Tax
Value added tax
Chapter 6: INDIRECT TAXES: VALUE-ADDED TAX
Definition of Value Added Tax
Value added tax
VAT is based on the increase in value of a product or service at each stage of production or distribution.
However, a VAT is collected by the end retailer and is usually a flat tax, and is therefore frequently compared to a sales tax.
Value-added taxation is based on taxpayers’ consumption rather than their income. In contrast to a progressive income tax, which levies greater taxes on higher-level earners, VAT applies equally to every purchase.
Слайд 176Map of countries and territories by their VAT status
VAT
No VAT
Map of countries and territories by their VAT status
VAT
No VAT
Слайд 177Standard VAT or sales tax rate
Standard VAT or sales tax rate
Слайд 178Value Added Tax Rates in Europe
Value Added Tax Rates in Europe
Слайд 179VAT Calculation Principles
A VAT is levied on the gross margin at each
VAT Calculation Principles
A VAT is levied on the gross margin at each
The VAT is assessed and collected at each stage, in contrast to a sales tax, which is only assessed and paid by the consumer at the very end of the supply chain.
The amount of VAT that the user pays is on the cost of the product, less any of the costs of materials used in the product that have already been taxed.
How Value Added Tax Works
Слайд 180Example 55:
Value Added Tax
Assume a VAT of 10%.
A farmer sells wheat
Example 55:
Value Added Tax
Assume a VAT of 10%.
A farmer sells wheat
How Value Added Tax Works
GOVERNMENT
FARMER
BAKER
30¢ + 3¢
3¢
wheat
Слайд 181Example 55:
Value Added Tax
The baker uses the wheat to make bread and
Example 55:
Value Added Tax
The baker uses the wheat to make bread and
How Value Added Tax Works
GOVERNMENT
FARMER
BAKER
30¢ + 3¢
3¢
wheat
SUPERMARKET
70¢ + 7¢
7¢ – 3¢ = 4¢
bread
Слайд 182Example 55:
Value Added Tax
Finally, the supermarket sells the loaf of bread to
Example 55:
Value Added Tax
Finally, the supermarket sells the loaf of bread to
How Value Added Tax Works
GOVERNMENT
FARMER
BAKER
30¢ + 3¢
3¢
wheat
SUPERMARKET
70¢ + 7¢
7¢ – 3¢ = 4¢
bread
CUSTOMER
$1 + 10¢
10¢ – 7¢ = 3¢
bread
Слайд 183VAT vs. Sales Tax
Sales tax is assessed only once at the final
VAT vs. Sales Tax
Sales tax is assessed only once at the final
Unlike VAT, which is assessed at each stage of purchase/production and paid by every successive buyer, sales tax is paid only once by the final consumer.
A key advantage of VAT over sales tax is that the former can allocate the tax amount to different stages at production based on the value added at that stage. Since sales tax is only paid once by the final buyer, one cannot measure the value added at each production stage. It makes it difficult to track and allocate the sales tax to specific stages of production.
How Value Added Tax Works
Слайд 184VAT: Advantages
Adoption of a regressive tax system, such as VAT, gives people
VAT: Advantages
Adoption of a regressive tax system, such as VAT, gives people
VAT also makes it harder to evade taxes, as the tax is already embedded in the purchase of goods and services.
Conclusion:
The regressive tax can provide strong incentives to work, which can boost the overall gross domestic product (GDP) of an economy.
It can also increase government revenues by reducing tax evasion and providing a more timely and efficient framework for collecting taxes.
How Value Added Tax Works
Слайд 185VAT: Disadvantages
Unlike the income tax rate, which varies at different levels of
VAT: Disadvantages
Unlike the income tax rate, which varies at different levels of
With VAT, goods and services become more expensive, and the entire tax is passed on to the consumers. It reduces the purchasing power of consumers and may make it difficult for low-income individuals and households to purchase necessities.
Businesses are faced with increased costs due to the administrative burden of calculating taxes at each stage of production. It can be especially challenging for global firms and multinational corporations with global supply chains spanning multiple tax regimes.
How Value Added Tax Works
Слайд 186Value Added Tax (U.K. case)
The basic principle of VAT is that tax
Value Added Tax (U.K. case)
The basic principle of VAT is that tax
This is achieved as follows:
Traders who are registered for VAT are required to charge VAT on their sales and must account for this output tax to HMRC, but
(b) such traders are allowed to recover from HMRC the input tax which they pay to their own suppliers, so that
(c) in effect, registered traders suffer no VAT and the total VAT is borne by the consumer at the end of the distribution chain.
Value Added Tax Calculation Examples
Слайд 187Example 57:
A Ltd owns a quarry. It extracts stone from this quarry
Example 57:
A Ltd owns a quarry. It extracts stone from this quarry
B Ltd converts all of the stone into paving slabs and sells these slabs to C Ltd for £18,000, plus VAT.
C Ltd owns a garden centre, where the paving slabs are sold to the general public for a total of £32,000, plus VAT.
Show how VAT is charged and collected at each stage of this process, assuming that VAT is to be calculated at 20% throughout.
Value Added Tax Calculation Examples
Слайд 188Example 57:
A Ltd owns a quarry. It extracts stone from this quarry
Example 57:
A Ltd owns a quarry. It extracts stone from this quarry
B Ltd converts all of the stone into paving slabs and sells these slabs to C Ltd for £18,000, plus VAT.
C Ltd owns a garden centre, where the paving slabs are sold to the general public for a total of £32,000, plus VAT.
Solution:
Value Added Tax Calculation Examples
Слайд 189Chapter 7: INTERNATIONAL TAXATION ASPECTS
Taxation Systems
Countries that tax income generally use one
Chapter 7: INTERNATIONAL TAXATION ASPECTS
Taxation Systems
Countries that tax income generally use one
Territorial tax system
Residential tax system
A country that taxes income sourced within its borders is said to impose source jurisdiction, also referred to as a territorial tax system.
Countries may also impose tax based on residency, called residence jurisdiction, whereby all income (domestic and foreign sourced) is subject to taxation.
Most countries use a residential tax system.
Слайд 191Taxation of income
Under source jurisdiction a country levies taxes on all income
Taxation of income
Under source jurisdiction a country levies taxes on all income
Under residence jurisdiction (the most prevalent type), a country taxes the income of its residents, whether generated inside or outside the country.
Persons subject to residence jurisdiction are taxed on their worldwide income. Most countries impose residence jurisdiction on noncitizen residents, but not citizens who are non-resident in the jurisdiction.
Source Jurisdiction vs. Residence Jurisdiction
Слайд 192Double Taxation Conflicts
Interaction of country tax systems can result in tax conflicts
Double Taxation Conflicts
Interaction of country tax systems can result in tax conflicts
Residence-residence conflict:
e.g., two countries claim residence for the same individual and hence claim taxing authority over the individual’s world-wide assets and income.
Source-source conflict:
e.g., think of a multinational company with operations that generate income in several countries.
Residence-source conflict:
The individual’s world-wide assets and income are taxed by the residence jurisdiction, and income generated by the foreign assets is taxed again under the source jurisdiction. Most common source of double taxation.
e.g., a U.S. citizen owning Singapore situated real estate would be subject to US income tax and Singapore income tax on rental income from property.
In response, some countries have adopted policies that help relieve the double taxation.
Tax Conflicts
Слайд 193Foreign Tax Credit Provisions
A residence country may choose to unilaterally provide its
Foreign Tax Credit Provisions
A residence country may choose to unilaterally provide its
credit method,
exemption method
deduction method.
Tax Conflicts
Слайд 194Foreign Tax Credit Provisions
A residence country may choose to unilaterally provide its
Foreign Tax Credit Provisions
A residence country may choose to unilaterally provide its
CREDIT METHOD
Residence country reduces its taxpayers’ domestic tax liability for taxes paid to a foreign country exercising source jurisdiction.
The credit is limited to the amount of taxes the taxpayer would pay domestically, which completely eliminates double taxation.
Tax liability equals the greater of the tax liability due in either the residence or source country:
Tax Conflicts
Слайд 195Foreign Tax Credit Provisions
A residence country may choose to unilaterally provide its
Foreign Tax Credit Provisions
A residence country may choose to unilaterally provide its
CREDIT METHOD
Example 58:
Suppose a residence country imposes a 50% tax on world-wide income but offers a relief for tax paid on foreign-sourced income via the credit method.
If the foreign government taxes the foreign-sourced income at 40%, the taxpayer will pay a 50% tax rate (e.g., Max [50%, 40%]).
Of the total, 40% is paid to foreign tax authorities and 10% is paid to the domestic authorities.
Tax Conflicts
Слайд 196Foreign Tax Credit Provisions
A residence country may choose to unilaterally provide its
Foreign Tax Credit Provisions
A residence country may choose to unilaterally provide its
EXEMPTION METHOD
Residence country imposes no tax on foreign-source income by providing taxpayers with an exemption, which, in effect, eliminates the residence–source conflict by having only one jurisdiction impose tax.
The tax liability under the exemption method is simply the tax imposed at the foreign source, or:
Tax Conflicts
Слайд 197Foreign Tax Credit Provisions
A residence country may choose to unilaterally provide its
Foreign Tax Credit Provisions
A residence country may choose to unilaterally provide its
EXEMPTION METHOD
Example 59:
Suppose a residence country imposes a 50% tax on world-wide income and the foreign government taxes the foreign-sourced income at 40%.
Under the exemption method, the tax liability would be 40%, all of which is collected by the foreign taxing authority.
Tax Conflicts
Слайд 198Foreign Tax Credit Provisions
A residence country may choose to unilaterally provide its
Foreign Tax Credit Provisions
A residence country may choose to unilaterally provide its
DEDUCTION METHOD
Residence country allows taxpayers to reduce their taxable income by the amount of taxes paid to foreign governments in respect of foreign-source income (i.e., provides a tax deduction rather than a credit or exemption).
The taxpayer is still responsible for both taxes, but the aggregate liability is less than the sum of the two with the residence country reducing the size of its percentage claim by the product of the two tax rates.
Tax Conflicts
Слайд 199Foreign Tax Credit Provisions
A residence country may choose to unilaterally provide its
Foreign Tax Credit Provisions
A residence country may choose to unilaterally provide its
DEDUCTION METHOD
Residence country allows taxpayers to reduce their taxable income by the amount of taxes paid to foreign governments in respect of foreign-source income (i.e., provides a tax deduction rather than a credit or exemption).
The taxpayer is still responsible for both taxes, but the aggregate liability is less than the sum of the two with the residence country reducing the size of its percentage claim by the product of the two tax rates.
Tax Conflicts
Слайд 200Foreign Tax Credit Provisions
A residence country may choose to unilaterally provide its
Foreign Tax Credit Provisions
A residence country may choose to unilaterally provide its
DEDUCTION METHOD
Example 60:
Suppose a residence country imposes a 50% tax on world-wide income and the foreign government taxes the foreign-sourced income at 40%.
Under the deduction method, the total tax liability equals
70% = 0.50 + 0.40 − (0.50 × 0.40).
In this case, the source country receives 40% and the residence country receives 30% [i.e., 0.50 − (0.50 × 0.40)]. The residence country makes a partial concession recognizing the primacy of source jurisdiction.
Tax Conflicts
Слайд 201Double Taxation Treaties
Relief from double taxation may be provided through a double
Double Taxation Treaties
Relief from double taxation may be provided through a double
Purpose:
Facilitate international trade and investment by eliminating double taxation.
By limiting source jurisdiction, DTTs resolve residence–source conflicts that are the most frequent cause of double taxation.
Virtually all modern tax treaties are based on the OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development) Model Treaty.
Model Treaty sanctions the exemption and credit method to resolve residence
source conflicts.
Tax Conflicts
Слайд 202Double Taxation Treaties
In addition to residence–source conflicts, DTTs resolve residence–residence conflicts.
A
Double Taxation Treaties
In addition to residence–source conflicts, DTTs resolve residence–residence conflicts.
A
In case of “dual residency” conflict, the following taxpayer’s criteria are used:
permanent home
center of vital interests
habitual dwelling
citizenship
DTTs typically do not resolve source–source conflicts.
Tax Conflicts
Слайд 203Tax Avoidance vs. Tax Evasion
Tax avoidance (a.k.a. “tax minimization”) uses legal means
Tax Avoidance vs. Tax Evasion
Tax avoidance (a.k.a. “tax minimization”) uses legal means
e.g., changing the asset location of high-dividend-paying equities that a taxpayer owns from a taxable account to a retirement account with tax-free earnings and withdrawals.
A company may choose to avoid taxes by establishing their company or subsidiaries in an offshore jurisdiction. Individuals may also avoid tax by moving their tax residence to a tax haven.
Tax evasion is the practice of circumventing tax obligations by illegal means such as misreporting or not reporting relevant information to tax authorities.
e.g., placing assets in jurisdictions with bank secrecy laws to avoid detection by taxing authorities in an individual’s home country. Income on these “undeclared funds” would therefore escape taxation by the home country that might otherwise impose a tax obligation if the income were reported.
Tax Avoidance and Tax Evasion
Слайд 204Current Trends in International Transparency and Information Exchange
Most countries attempt to maximize
Current Trends in International Transparency and Information Exchange
Most countries attempt to maximize
Examples:
1. In an effort to maximize world-wide taxation on its residents and citizens, the United States demands that global banks disclose the names of U.S. securities’ owners, whether U.S. citizens or not.
Tax Avoidance and Tax Evasion
Слайд 205Current Trends in International Transparency and Information Exchange
Most countries attempt to maximize
Current Trends in International Transparency and Information Exchange
Most countries attempt to maximize
Examples:
2. European Union Savings Directive (EUSD), a directive on the taxation of interest income from savings within the EU, was created in 2005.
Under the EUSD system, EU member banks agree to automatically exchange customer information with each other.
As a result, a EU withholding tax was introduced to ensure that citizens of one member state do not evade taxation by depositing funds outside the jurisdiction of residence and so distort the single market. The tax is withheld at source and passed on to the EU Country of residence.
Note:
The EU withholding tax is levied only on individuals and not on companies, discretionary trusts, foundations, investment funds. The EU withholding tax applies only to bank interest, bond interest, and analogous income, such as income from money market funds, loans, and mortgages.
Tax Avoidance and Tax Evasion
Слайд 206Current Trends in International Transparency and Information Exchange
Most countries attempt to maximize
Current Trends in International Transparency and Information Exchange
Most countries attempt to maximize
Examples:
3. In some cases authorities collect information from credit card companies about individuals who use credit cards in their country, whether or not they are citizens of that country. This information can then be shared with the individual’s home country.
Tax Avoidance and Tax Evasion
Слайд 207Common Tax Evasion Schemes
Falsifying information on tax return
This occurs when a taxpayer
Common Tax Evasion Schemes
Falsifying information on tax return
This occurs when a taxpayer
Paying in Cash
An employer pays their employees in cash and fails to report to the taxing authority the full amount that was paid.
Pyramiding payroll taxes
A company that withholds payroll taxes from its employees intentionally fails to remit those withholdings to the taxing authority. The company continues to accumulate (“pyramid”) employment tax liabilities beyond its ability to pay, so it may close down, and then start up again within a new entity having a new employer identification number.
Tax Avoidance and Tax Evasion
Слайд 208Transfer Pricing
Transfer pricing is an accounting practice that represents the price that
Transfer Pricing
Transfer pricing is an accounting practice that represents the price that
Multinational corporations are legally allowed to use the transfer pricing method for allocating earnings among their various subsidiary and affiliate companies that are part of the parent organization.
However, companies at times can also use (or misuse) this practice by altering their taxable income, thus reducing their overall taxes.
The transfer pricing mechanism is a way that companies can shift tax liabilities to low-cost tax jurisdictions known as tax havens.
Transfer Pricing
Слайд 209Example 62:
Transfer Pricing as a Tax Reduction Strategy
A U.S. parent has
Example 62:
Transfer Pricing as a Tax Reduction Strategy
A U.S. parent has
Transfer Pricing
FOREIGN MANUFACTURING SUBSIDIARY
U.S. PARENT COMPANY
Sell inventory at $150 or
$120 / unit
Cost to manufacturer = $100 / unit
?
CUSTOMERS
Sell at $200 / unit
Слайд 210Example 62:
Transfer Pricing as a Tax Reduction Strategy
A U.S. parent has
Example 62:
Transfer Pricing as a Tax Reduction Strategy
A U.S. parent has
If the U.S. tax rate is higher than the foreign rate, the firm would like to set a high transfer price. Assume the U.S. and foreign tax rates are 35% and 20%, respectively.
The analysis setting a low(higher) transfer price is as follows:
Transfer Pricing
FOREIGN MANUFACTURING SUBSIDIARY
U.S. PARENT COMPANY
Sell inventory at $150 or
$120 / unit
Cost to manufacturer = $100 / unit
CUSTOMERS
Sell at $200 / unit
t = 35%
t = 20%
Слайд 211Example 62:
Transfer Pricing as a Tax Reduction Strategy
A U.S. parent has
Example 62:
Transfer Pricing as a Tax Reduction Strategy
A U.S. parent has
Transfer Pricing
FOREIGN MANUFACTURING SUBSIDIARY
U.S. PARENT COMPANY
Sell inventory at $150 or
$120 / unit
Cost to manufacturer = $100 / unit
CUSTOMERS
Sell at $200 / unit
t = 35%
t = 20%
Слайд 212Example 62:
Transfer Pricing as a Tax Reduction Strategy
A U.S. parent has
Example 62:
Transfer Pricing as a Tax Reduction Strategy
A U.S. parent has
Transfer Pricing
FOREIGN MANUFACTURING SUBSIDIARY
U.S. PARENT COMPANY
Sell inventory at $150 or
$120 / unit
Cost to manufacturer = $100 / unit
CUSTOMERS
Sell at $200 / unit
t = 35%
t = 20%
Слайд 213Example 62:
Transfer Pricing as a Tax Reduction Strategy
A U.S. parent has
Example 62:
Transfer Pricing as a Tax Reduction Strategy
A U.S. parent has
Conclusion: a firm can save $4.5 per unit on taxes by setting a high transfer price.
Transfer Pricing
FOREIGN MANUFACTURING SUBSIDIARY
U.S. PARENT COMPANY
Sell inventory at $150 or
$120 / unit
Cost to manufacturer = $100 / unit
CUSTOMERS
Sell at $200 / unit
t = 35%
t = 20%
Слайд 214Transfer Pricing via Tax Haven
Transfer pricing is a technique used by multinational
Transfer Pricing via Tax Haven
Transfer pricing is a technique used by multinational
Example 63:
Assume it costs a multinational corporation $100 to produce a crate of bananas in Ecuador. It then sells that crate to an affiliate located in a tax haven for $100, leaving no profits in Ecuador.
The tax haven affiliate immediately sells that crate on to an affiliate in Poland for $300, leaving $200 profit in the tax haven.
That Polish affiliate sells the crate at the genuine market price of $300 to a supermarket, leaving no profits in Poland. As a result, the multinational pays no tax in Ecuador and no tax in Poland, and the $200 in profits shifted to the tax haven do not get taxed.
Transfer Pricing
Слайд 215Tax Haven
A tax haven (a.k.a., offshore financial center) is a tax jurisdiction
Tax Haven
A tax haven (a.k.a., offshore financial center) is a tax jurisdiction
Tax havens do not require businesses to operate out of their country or the individuals to reside in their country to receive tax benefits.
Criteria for Tax Havens
No, or nominal, tax on relevant income
Lack of effective exchange of information
Lack of transparency
No substantial activities
Tax Havens
OECD, 1998