Ricardian model

Содержание

Слайд 2

Preview

Opportunity costs and comparative advantage
A one-factor Ricardian model
Production possibilities
Gains from trade
Wages and

Preview Opportunity costs and comparative advantage A one-factor Ricardian model Production possibilities
trade
Misconceptions about comparative advantage
Transportation costs and non-traded goods
Empirical evidence

Слайд 3

Introduction

Theories of why trade occurs:
Differences across countries in labor, labor skills, physical

Introduction Theories of why trade occurs: Differences across countries in labor, labor
capital, natural resources, and technology
Economies of scale (larger scale of production is more efficient)

Слайд 4

Introduction (cont.)

Sources of differences across countries that lead to gains from trade:
The

Introduction (cont.) Sources of differences across countries that lead to gains from
Ricardian model (Econ/Trade Chapter 3) examines differences in the productivity of labor (due to differences in technology) between countries.
The Heckscher-Ohlin model (Econ/Trade Chapter 4) examines differences in labor, labor skills, physical capital, land, or other factors of production between countries.

Слайд 5

Comparative Advantage and Opportunity Cost

The Ricardian model uses the concepts of opportunity

Comparative Advantage and Opportunity Cost The Ricardian model uses the concepts of
cost and comparative advantage.
The opportunity cost of producing something measures the cost of not being able to produce something else with the resources used.

Слайд 6

Comparative Advantage and Opportunity Cost (cont.)

For example, a limited number of workers

Comparative Advantage and Opportunity Cost (cont.) For example, a limited number of
could produce either roses or computers.
The opportunity cost of producing computers is the amount of roses not produced.
The opportunity cost of producing roses is the amount of computers not produced.

Слайд 7

Comparative Advantage and Opportunity Cost (cont.)

Suppose that in the United States 10

Comparative Advantage and Opportunity Cost (cont.) Suppose that in the United States
million roses could be produced with the same resources as 100,000 computers.
Suppose that in Colombia 10 million roses could be produced with the same resources as 30,000 computers.
Colombia has a lower opportunity cost of producing roses: has to stop producing fewer computers.

Слайд 8

Comparative Advantage and Opportunity Cost (cont.)

A country has a comparative advantage in

Comparative Advantage and Opportunity Cost (cont.) A country has a comparative advantage
producing a good if the opportunity cost of producing that good is lower in the country than in other countries.
The United States has a comparative advantage in computer production.
Colombia has a comparative advantage in rose production.

Слайд 9

Comparative Advantage and Opportunity Cost (cont.)

Suppose initially that Colombia produces computers and

Comparative Advantage and Opportunity Cost (cont.) Suppose initially that Colombia produces computers
the United States produces roses, and that both countries want to consume computers and roses.
Can both countries be made better off?

Слайд 10

Table 3-1: Hypothetical Changes in Production

Table 3-1: Hypothetical Changes in Production

Слайд 11

Comparative Advantage and Trade

When countries specialize in production in which they

Comparative Advantage and Trade When countries specialize in production in which they
have a comparative advantage, more goods and services can be produced and consumed.
Have the United States stop growing roses and use those resources to make 100,000 computers instead. Have Colombia stop making 30,000 computers and grow roses instead.
If produce goods in which have a comparative advantage (the United States produces computers and Colombia roses), they could still consume the same 10 million roses, but could consume 100,000 – 30,000 = 70,000 more computers.

Слайд 12

A One-Factor Ricardian Model

The simple example with roses and computers explains the

A One-Factor Ricardian Model The simple example with roses and computers explains
intuition behind the Ricardian model.
We formalize these ideas by constructing a one-factor Ricardian model using the following assumptions:

Слайд 13

A One-Factor Ricardian Model (cont.)

Labor is the only factor of production.
Labor productivity

A One-Factor Ricardian Model (cont.) Labor is the only factor of production.
varies across countries due to differences in technology, but labor productivity in each country is constant.
The supply of labor in each country is constant.

Слайд 14

A One-Factor Ricardian Model (cont.)

Two goods: wine and cheese.
Competition allows workers to

A One-Factor Ricardian Model (cont.) Two goods: wine and cheese. Competition allows
be paid a wage equal to the value of what they produce, and allows them to work in the industry that pays the highest wage.
Two countries: home and foreign.

Слайд 15

A One-Factor Ricardian Model (cont.)

A unit labor requirement indicates the constant number

A One-Factor Ricardian Model (cont.) A unit labor requirement indicates the constant
of hours of labor required to produce one unit of output.
aLC is the unit labor requirement for cheese in the home country. For example, aLC = 1 means that 1 hour of labor produces one pound of cheese in the home country.
aLW is the unit labor requirement for wine in the home country. For example, aLW = 2 means that 2 hours of labor produces one gallon of wine in the home country.
A high unit labor requirement means low labor productivity.

Слайд 16

A One-Factor Ricardian Model (cont.)

Labor supply L indicates the total number of

A One-Factor Ricardian Model (cont.) Labor supply L indicates the total number
hours worked in the home country (a constant number).
Cheese production QC indicates how many pounds of cheese are produced.
Wine production QW indicates how many gallons of wine are produced.

Слайд 17

Production Possibilities

The production possibility frontier (PPF) of an economy shows the maximum

Production Possibilities The production possibility frontier (PPF) of an economy shows the
amount of a goods that can be produced for a fixed amount of resources.
The production possibility frontier of the home economy is:
aLCQC + aLWQW ≤ L

Слайд 18

Production Possibilities (cont.)

Maximum home cheese production is QC = L/aLC when QW =

Production Possibilities (cont.) Maximum home cheese production is QC = L/aLC when
0.
Maximum home wine production is QW = L/aLW when QC = 0.

Слайд 19

Production Possibilities (cont.)

For example, suppose that the economy’s labor supply is 1,000

Production Possibilities (cont.) For example, suppose that the economy’s labor supply is
hours.
The PPF equation aLCQC + aLWQW ≤ L becomes QC + 2QW ≤ 1,000.
Maximum cheese production is 1,000 pounds.
Maximum wine production is 500 gallons.

Слайд 20

Fig. 3-1: Home’s Production Possibility Frontier

Fig. 3-1: Home’s Production Possibility Frontier

Слайд 21

Production Possibilities (cont.)

The opportunity cost of cheese is how many gallons of

Production Possibilities (cont.) The opportunity cost of cheese is how many gallons
wine Home must stop producing in order to make one more pound of cheese:
aLC /aLW
This cost is constant because the unit labor requirements are both constant.
The opportunity cost of cheese appears as the absolute value of the slope of the PPF.
QW = L/aLW – (aLC /aLW )QC

Слайд 22

Production Possibilities (cont.)

Producing an additional pound of cheese requires aLC hours of

Production Possibilities (cont.) Producing an additional pound of cheese requires aLC hours
labor.
Each hour devoted to cheese production could have been used instead to produce an amount of wine equal to
1 hour/(aLW hours/gallon of wine)
= (1/aLW) gallons of wine

Слайд 23

Production Possibilities (cont.)

For example, if 1 hour of labor is moved to

Production Possibilities (cont.) For example, if 1 hour of labor is moved
cheese production, that additional hour could have produced
1 hour/(2 hours/gallon of wine)
= ½ gallon of wine.
Opportunity cost of producing one pound of cheese is ½ gallon of wine not produced.

Слайд 24

Relative Prices, Wages, and Supply

Let PC be the price of cheese and

Relative Prices, Wages, and Supply Let PC be the price of cheese
PW be the price of wine.
Due to competition,
hourly wages of cheese makers equal the value of the cheese produced in an hour: PC /aLC
hourly wages of wine makers equal the value of the wine produced in an hour: PW /aLW
Workers will choose to work in the industry that pays the higher wage.

Слайд 25

Relative Prices, Wages, and Supply (cont.)

If the price of cheese relative to

Relative Prices, Wages, and Supply (cont.) If the price of cheese relative
the price of wine exceeds the opportunity cost of producing cheese PC /PW > aLC /aLW ,
Then the wage in cheese will exceed the wage in wine wC =PC /aLC > PW/aLW =wW
So workers will make only cheese (the economy specializes in cheese production).

Слайд 26

Relative Prices, Wages, and Supply (cont.)

If the price of cheese relative to

Relative Prices, Wages, and Supply (cont.) If the price of cheese relative
the price of wine is less than the opportunity cost of producing cheese PC /PW < aLC /aLW ,
then the wage in cheese will be less than the wage in wine PC /aLC < PW/aLW
so workers will make only wine (the economy specializes in wine production).

Слайд 27

Production, Prices, and Wages

If the price of cheese relative to the price

Production, Prices, and Wages If the price of cheese relative to the
of wine equals the opportunity cost of producing cheese PC /PW = aLC /aLW ,
then the wage in cheese equals the wage in wine PC /aLC = PW/aLW
so workers will be willing to make both wine and cheese.

Слайд 28

Production, Prices, and Wages (cont.)

For example, suppose cheese sells for PC =

Production, Prices, and Wages (cont.) For example, suppose cheese sells for PC
$4/pound and wine sells for PW = $7/gallon.
Wage paid producing cheese is PC /aLC = ($4/pound)(1 pound/hour) = $4/hour.
Wage paid producing wine is PW /aLW = ($7/gallon)(1/2 gallon/hour) = $3.50/hour.
Workers would be willing to make only cheese (the relative price of cheese 4/7 exceeds the opportunity cost of cheese of ½).

Слайд 29

Production, Prices, and Wages (cont.)

If the price of cheese drops to PC

Production, Prices, and Wages (cont.) If the price of cheese drops to
= $3/pound:
Wage paid producing cheese drops to PC /aLC = ($3/pound)(1 pound/hour) = $3/hour.
Wage paid producing wine is still $3.50/hour if price of wine is still $7/gallon.
Now workers would be willing to make only wine (the relative price of cheese 3/7 is now less than the opportunity cost of cheese of ½).

Слайд 30

Production, Prices, and Wages (cont.)

If the home country wants to consume both

Production, Prices, and Wages (cont.) If the home country wants to consume
wine and cheese (in the absence of international trade), relative prices must adjust so that wages are equal in the wine and cheese industries.
If PC /aLC = PW /aLW workers will not care whether they work in the cheese industry or the wine industry, so that production of both goods can occur.
Production (and consumption) of both goods occurs when the relative price of a good equals the opportunity cost of producing that good:
PC /PW = aLC /aLW

Слайд 31

Trade in the Ricardian Model

If the home country is more efficient in

Trade in the Ricardian Model If the home country is more efficient
wine and cheese production, then it has an absolute advantage in all production:
its unit labor requirements for wine and cheese production are lower than those in the foreign country
aLC < a*LC and aLW < a*LW
where “*” notates foreign country variables

Слайд 32

Trade in the Ricardian Model (cont.)

A country can be more efficient in

Trade in the Ricardian Model (cont.) A country can be more efficient
producing both goods, but it will have a comparative advantage in only one good.
Even if a country is the most (or least) efficient producer of all goods, it still can benefit from trade.

Слайд 33

Trade in the Ricardian Model (cont.)

Suppose that the home country has a

Trade in the Ricardian Model (cont.) Suppose that the home country has
comparative advantage in cheese production: its opportunity cost of producing cheese is lower than in the foreign country.
aLC /aLW < a*LC /a*LW
When the home country increases cheese production, it reduces wine production less than the foreign country would.

Слайд 34

Trade in the Ricardian Model (cont.)

Since the slope of the PPF indicates

Trade in the Ricardian Model (cont.) Since the slope of the PPF
the opportunity cost of cheese in terms of wine, Foreign’s PPF is steeper than Home’s.
To produce one pound of cheese, must stop producing more gallons of wine in Foreign than in Home.

Слайд 35

Fig. 3-2: Foreign’s Production Possibility Frontier

Fig. 3-2: Foreign’s Production Possibility Frontier

Слайд 36

Trade in the Ricardian Model (cont.)

Before any trade occurs, the relative price

Trade in the Ricardian Model (cont.) Before any trade occurs, the relative
of cheese to wine reflects the opportunity cost of cheese in terms of wine in each country.
In the absence of any trade, the relative price of cheese to wine will be higher in Foreign than in Home if Foreign has the higher opportunity cost of cheese.
It will be profitable to ship cheese from Home to Foreign (and wine from Foreign to Home) – where does the relative price of cheese to wine settle?

Слайд 37

Trade in the Ricardian Model (cont.)

To see how all countries can benefit

Trade in the Ricardian Model (cont.) To see how all countries can
from trade, need to find relative prices when trade exists.
First calculate the world relative supply of cheese: the quantity of cheese supplied by all countries relative to the quantity of wine supplied by all countries
RS = (QC + Q*C )/(QW + Q*W)

Слайд 38

Relative Supply and Relative Demand

If the relative price of cheese falls below

Relative Supply and Relative Demand If the relative price of cheese falls
the opportunity cost of cheese in both countries PC /PW < aLC /aLW < a*LC /a*LW,
no cheese would be produced.
domestic and foreign workers would be willing to produce only wine (where wage is higher).

Слайд 39

Relative Supply and Relative Demand (cont.)

When the relative price of cheese equals

Relative Supply and Relative Demand (cont.) When the relative price of cheese
the opportunity cost in the home country PC /PW = aLC /aLW < a*LC /a*LW ,
domestic workers are indifferent about producing wine or cheese (wage when producing wine same as wage when producing cheese).
foreign workers produce only wine.

Слайд 40

Relative Supply and Relative Demand (cont.)

When the relative price of cheese settles

Relative Supply and Relative Demand (cont.) When the relative price of cheese
strictly in between the opportunity costs of cheese aLC /aLW < Pc /PW < a*LC /a*LW ,
domestic workers produce only cheese (where their wages are higher).
foreign workers still produce only wine (where their wages are higher).
world relative supply of cheese equals Home’s maximum cheese production divided by Foreign’s maximum wine production (L / aLC ) / (L*/ a*LW).

Слайд 41

Relative Supply and Relative Demand (cont.)

When the relative price of cheese equals

Relative Supply and Relative Demand (cont.) When the relative price of cheese
the opportunity cost in the foreign country
aLC /aLW < PC /PW = a*LC /a*LW ,
foreign workers are indifferent about producing wine or cheese (wage when producing wine same as wage when producing cheese).
domestic workers produce only cheese.

Слайд 42

Relative Supply and Relative Demand (cont.)

If the relative price of cheese rises

Relative Supply and Relative Demand (cont.) If the relative price of cheese
above the opportunity cost of cheese in both countries
aLC /aLW < a*LC /a*LW < PC /PW,
no wine is produced.
home and foreign workers are willing to produce only cheese (where wage is higher).

Слайд 43

Relative Supply and Relative Demand (cont.)

World relative supply is a step function:
First

Relative Supply and Relative Demand (cont.) World relative supply is a step
step at relative price of cheese equal to Home’s opportunity cost aLC /aLW, which equals 1/2 in the example.
Jumps when world relative supply of cheese equals Home’s maximum cheese production divided by Foreign’s maximum wine production (L / aLC ) / (L*/ a*LW), which equals 1 in the example.
Second step at relative price of cheese equal to Foreign’s opportunity cost a*LC /a*LW, which equals 2 in the example.

Слайд 44

Relative Supply and Relative Demand (cont.)

Relative demand of cheese is the quantity

Relative Supply and Relative Demand (cont.) Relative demand of cheese is the
of cheese demanded in all countries relative to the quantity of wine demanded in all countries.
As the price of cheese relative to the price of wine rises, consumers in all countries will tend to purchase less cheese and more wine so that the relative quantity demanded of cheese falls.

Слайд 45

Fig. 3-3: World Relative Supply and Demand

Fig. 3-3: World Relative Supply and Demand

Слайд 46

Gains from Trade

Gains from trade come from specializing in the type of

Gains from Trade Gains from trade come from specializing in the type
production which uses resources most efficiently, and using the income generated from that production to buy the goods and services that countries desire.
where “using resources most efficiently” means producing a good in which a country has a comparative advantage.

Слайд 47

Gains from Trade (cont.)

Domestic workers earn a higher income from cheese production

Gains from Trade (cont.) Domestic workers earn a higher income from cheese
because the relative price of cheese increases with trade.
Foreign workers earn a higher income from wine production because the relative price of cheese decreases with trade (making cheese cheaper) and the relative price of wine increases with trade.

Слайд 48

Gains from Trade (cont.)

Think of trade as an indirect method of production

Gains from Trade (cont.) Think of trade as an indirect method of
that converts cheese into wine or vice versa.
Without trade, a country has to allocate resources to produce all of the goods that it wants to consume.
With trade, a country can specialize its production and exchange for the mix of goods that it wants to consume.

Слайд 49

Gains from Trade (cont.)

Consumption possibilities expand beyond the production possibility frontier when

Gains from Trade (cont.) Consumption possibilities expand beyond the production possibility frontier
trade is allowed.
With trade, consumption in each country is expanded because world production is expanded when each country specializes in producing the good in which it has a comparative advantage.

Слайд 50

Fig. 3-4: Trade Expands Consumption Possibilities

Fig. 3-4: Trade Expands Consumption Possibilities

Слайд 51

A Numerical Example

What is the home country’s opportunity cost of producing cheese?

A Numerical Example What is the home country’s opportunity cost of producing
aLC /aLW = ½, to produce one pound of cheese, stop producing ½ gallon of wine.

Unit labor requirements for home and foreign countries

Слайд 52

A Numerical Example (cont.)

The home country is more efficient in both industries,

A Numerical Example (cont.) The home country is more efficient in both
but has a comparative advantage only in cheese production.
1/2 = aLC /aLW < a*LC /a*LW = 2
The foreign country is less efficient in both industries, but has a comparative advantage in wine production.

Слайд 53

A Numerical Example (cont.)

With trade, the equilibrium relative price of cheese to

A Numerical Example (cont.) With trade, the equilibrium relative price of cheese
wine settles between the two opportunity costs of cheese.
Suppose that the intersection of RS and RD occurs at PC /PW = 1 so one pound of cheese trades for one gallon of wine.
Trade causes the relative price of cheese to rise in the home country and fall in foreign.

Слайд 54

A Numerical Example (cont.)

With trade, the foreign country can buy one pound

A Numerical Example (cont.) With trade, the foreign country can buy one
of cheese for PC /PW = one gallon of wine,
instead of stopping production of a*LC /a*LW = 2 gallons of wine to free up enough labor to produce one pound of cheese in the absence of trade.
Suppose L* = 3,000. The foreign country can trade its 1,000 gallons maximum production of wine for 1,000 pounds of cheese, instead of the 500 pounds of cheese it could produce itself.

Слайд 55

A Numerical Example (cont.)

With trade, the home country can buy one gallon

A Numerical Example (cont.) With trade, the home country can buy one
of wine for PW /PC = one pound of cheese,
instead of stopping production of aLW /aLC = two pounds of cheese to free up enough labor to produce one gallon of wine in the absence of trade.
The home country can trade its 1,000 pounds maximum production of cheese for 1,000 gallons of wine, instead of the 500 gallons of wine it could produce itself.

Слайд 56

Relative Wages

Relative wages are the wages of the home country relative to

Relative Wages Relative wages are the wages of the home country relative
the wages in the foreign country.
Productivity (technological) differences determine relative wage differences across countries.
The home wage relative to the foreign wage will settle in between the ratio of how much better Home is at making cheese and how much better it is at making wine compared to Foreign.
Relative wages cause Home to have a cost advantage in only cheese and Foreign to have a cost advantage in only wine.

Слайд 57

Relative Wages (cont.)

Suppose that PC = $12/pound and PW = $12/gallon.
Since domestic

Relative Wages (cont.) Suppose that PC = $12/pound and PW = $12/gallon.
workers specialize in cheese production after trade, their hourly wages will be
PC/aLC = $12 /1= $12
Since foreign workers specialize in wine production after trade, their hourly wages will be
PW/a*LW = $12/3 = $4
The relative wage of domestic workers is therefore
$12/$4 = 3

Слайд 58

Relative Wages (cont.)

The relative wage lies between the ratio of the productivities

Relative Wages (cont.) The relative wage lies between the ratio of the
in each industry.
The home country is 6/1 = 6 times as productive in cheese production, but only 3/2 = 1.5 times as productive in wine production.
The home country has a wage 3 times higher than the foreign country.

Слайд 59

Relative Wages (cont.)

These relationships imply that both countries have a cost advantage

Relative Wages (cont.) These relationships imply that both countries have a cost
in production.
High wages can be offset by high productivity.
Low productivity can be offset by low wages.
In the home economy, producing one pound of cheese costs $12 (one worker paid $12/hr) but would have cost $24 (six paid $4/hr) in Foreign.
In the foreign economy, producing one gallon of wine costs $12 (three workers paid $4/hr) but would have cost $24 (two paid $12/hr) in Home.

Слайд 60

Relative Wages (cont.)

Because foreign workers have a wage that is only 1/3

Relative Wages (cont.) Because foreign workers have a wage that is only
the wage of domestic workers, they are able to attain a cost advantage in wine production, despite low productivity.
Because domestic workers have a productivity that is 6 times that of foreign workers in cheese production, they are able to attain a cost advantage in cheese production, despite high wages.

Слайд 61

Do Wages Reflect Productivity?

Do relative wages reflect relative productivities of the two

Do Wages Reflect Productivity? Do relative wages reflect relative productivities of the
countries?
Evidence shows that low wages are associated with low productivity.
Wage of most countries relative to the U.S. is similar to their productivity relative to the U.S.

Слайд 62

Productivity and Wages

Productivity and Wages

Слайд 63

Do Wages Reflect Productivity? (cont.)

Other evidence shows that wages rise as productivity

Do Wages Reflect Productivity? (cont.) Other evidence shows that wages rise as
rises.
As recently as 1975, wages in South Korea were only 5% of those of the United States.
As South Korea’s labor productivity rose (to about half of the U.S. level by 2007), so did its wages.

Слайд 64

Misconceptions about Comparative Advantage

Free trade is beneficial only if a country is

Misconceptions about Comparative Advantage Free trade is beneficial only if a country
more productive than foreign countries.
But even an unproductive country benefits from free trade by avoiding the high costs for goods that it would otherwise have to produce domestically.
High costs derive from inefficient use of resources.
The benefits of free trade do not depend on absolute advantage, rather they depend on comparative advantage: specializing in industries that use resources most efficiently.

Слайд 65

Misconceptions about Comparative Advantage (cont.)

Free trade with countries that pay low wages

Misconceptions about Comparative Advantage (cont.) Free trade with countries that pay low
hurts high wage countries.
While trade may reduce wages for some workers, thereby affecting the distribution of income within a country, trade benefits consumers and other workers.
Consumers benefit because they can purchase goods more cheaply.
Producers/workers benefit by earning a higher income in the industries that use resources more efficiently, allowing them to earn higher prices and wages.

Слайд 66

Misconceptions about Comparative Advantage (cont.)

Free trade exploits less productive countries whose workers

Misconceptions about Comparative Advantage (cont.) Free trade exploits less productive countries whose
make low wages.
While labor standards in some countries are less than exemplary compared to Western standards, they are so with or without trade.
Are high wages and safe labor practices alternatives to trade? Deeper poverty and exploitation may result without export production.
Consumers benefit from free trade by having access to cheaply (efficiently) produced goods.
Producers/workers benefit from having higher profits/wages—higher compared to the alternative.

Слайд 67

Comparative Advantage with Many Goods

Suppose now there are N goods produced, indexed

Comparative Advantage with Many Goods Suppose now there are N goods produced,
by i = 1,2,…N.
The home country’s unit labor requirement for good i is aLi, and the corresponding foreign unit labor requirement is a*Li .
Goods will be produced wherever cheapest to produce them.

Слайд 68

Comparative Advantage with Many Goods (cont.)

Let w represent the wage rate in

Comparative Advantage with Many Goods (cont.) Let w represent the wage rate
the home country and w* represent the wage rate in the foreign country.
If waL1 < w*a*L1 then only the home country will produce good 1, since total wage payments are less there.
Or equivalently, if a*L1 /aL1 > w/w*, if the relative productivity of a country in producing a good is higher than the relative wage, then the good will be produced in that country.

Слайд 69

Table 3-2: Home and Foreign Unit Labor Requirements

Table 3-2: Home and Foreign Unit Labor Requirements

Слайд 70

Comparative Advantage with Many Goods (cont.)

Suppose there are 5 goods produced in

Comparative Advantage with Many Goods (cont.) Suppose there are 5 goods produced
the world: apples, bananas, caviar, dates, and enchiladas.
If w/w* = 3, the home country will produce apples, bananas, and caviar, while the foreign country will produce dates and enchiladas.
The relative productivities of the home country in producing apples, bananas, and caviar are higher than the relative wage.

Слайд 71

Comparative Advantage with Many Goods (cont.)

If each country specializes in goods that

Comparative Advantage with Many Goods (cont.) If each country specializes in goods
use resources productively and trades the products for those that it wants to consume, then each benefits.
If a country tries to produce all goods for itself, resources are “wasted”.
The home country has high productivity in apples, bananas, and caviar that give it a cost advantage, despite its high wage.
The foreign country has low wages that give it a cost advantage, despite its low productivity in date production.

Слайд 72

Comparative Advantage with Many Goods (cont.)

How is the relative wage determined?
By the

Comparative Advantage with Many Goods (cont.) How is the relative wage determined?
relative supply of and relative (derived) demand for labor services.
The relative (derived) demand for home labor services falls when w/w* rises. As domestic labor services become more expensive relative to foreign labor services,
goods produced in the home country become more expensive, and demand for these goods and the labor services to produce them falls.
fewer goods will be produced in the home country, further reducing the demand for domestic labor services.

Слайд 73

Comparative Advantage with Many Goods (cont.)

Suppose w/w* increases from 3 to 3.99:
The

Comparative Advantage with Many Goods (cont.) Suppose w/w* increases from 3 to
home country would produce apples, bananas, and caviar, but the demand for these goods and the labor to produce them would fall as the relative wage rises.
Suppose w/w* increases from 3.99 to 4.01:
Caviar is now too expensive to produce in the home country, so the caviar industry moves to the foreign country, causing a discrete (abrupt) drop in the demand for domestic labor services.
Consider similar effects as w/w* rises from 0.75 to 10.

Слайд 74

Fig. 3-5: Determination of Relative Wages

Fig. 3-5: Determination of Relative Wages

Слайд 75

Comparative Advantage with Many Goods (cont.)

Finally, suppose that relative supply of labor

Comparative Advantage with Many Goods (cont.) Finally, suppose that relative supply of
is independent of w/w* and is fixed at an amount determined by the populations in the home and foreign countries.

Слайд 76

Transportation Costs and Non-traded Goods

The Ricardian model predicts that countries completely specialize

Transportation Costs and Non-traded Goods The Ricardian model predicts that countries completely
in production.
But this rarely happens for three main reasons:
More than one factor of production reduces the tendency of specialization (Econ/Trade Chapters 4-5).
Protectionism (Econ/Trade Chapters 9–12).
Transportation costs reduce or prevent trade, which may cause each country to produce the same good or service.

Слайд 77

Transportation Costs and Non-traded Goods (cont.)

Nontraded goods and services (ex., haircuts and

Transportation Costs and Non-traded Goods (cont.) Nontraded goods and services (ex., haircuts
auto repairs) exist due to high transport costs.
Countries tend to spend a large fraction of national income on nontraded goods and services.
This fact has implications for the gravity model and for models that consider how income transfers across countries affect trade.

Слайд 78

Empirical Evidence

Do countries export those goods in which their productivity is relatively

Empirical Evidence Do countries export those goods in which their productivity is
high?
The ratio of U.S. to British exports in 1951 compared to the ratio of U.S. to British labor productivity in 26 manufacturing industries suggests yes.
At this time the U.S. had an absolute advantage in all 26 industries, yet the ratio of exports was low in the least productive sectors of the U.S.

Слайд 79

Fig. 3-6: Productivity and Exports

Fig. 3-6: Productivity and Exports

Слайд 80

Empirical Evidence (cont.)

A very poor country like Bangladesh can have comparative advantage

Empirical Evidence (cont.) A very poor country like Bangladesh can have comparative
in clothing despite being less productive in clothing than other countries such as China because it is even less productive compared to China in other sectors.
Productivity (output per worker) in Bangladesh is only 28 percent of China’s on average.
In apparel, productivity in Bangladesh was about 77 percent of China’s, creating strong comparative advantage in apparel for Bangladesh.

Слайд 81

Table 3-3: Bangladesh versus China, 2011

Table 3-3: Bangladesh versus China, 2011

Слайд 82

Empirical Evidence (cont.)

The main implications of the Ricardian model are well supported

Empirical Evidence (cont.) The main implications of the Ricardian model are well
by empirical evidence:
productivity differences play an important role in international trade
comparative advantage (not absolute advantage) matters for trade

Слайд 83

Summary

Differences in the productivity of labor across countries generate comparative advantage.
A country

Summary Differences in the productivity of labor across countries generate comparative advantage.
has a comparative advantage in producing a good when its opportunity cost of producing that good is lower than in other countries.

Слайд 84

Summary (cont.)

Countries export goods in which they have a comparative advantage -

Summary (cont.) Countries export goods in which they have a comparative advantage
high productivity or low wages give countries a cost advantage.
With trade, the relative price settles in between what the relative prices were in each country before trade.
Имя файла: Ricardian-model.pptx
Количество просмотров: 60
Количество скачиваний: 0