Содержание

Слайд 2

The meaning of oligopoly, and why it occurs
Why oligopolists have an

The meaning of oligopoly, and why it occurs Why oligopolists have an
incentive to act in ways that reduce their combined profit, and why they can benefit from collusion
How our understanding of oligopoly can be enhanced by using game theory, especially the concept of the prisoners’ dilemma
How repeated interactions among oligopolists can help them achieve tacit collusion
How oligopoly works in practice, under the legal constraints of antitrust policy

Слайд 3

The Prevalence of Oligopoly

In addition to perfect competition and monopoly, oligopoly and

The Prevalence of Oligopoly In addition to perfect competition and monopoly, oligopoly
monopolistic competition are also important types of market structure. They are forms of imperfect competition.

Слайд 4

The Prevalence of Oligopoly

Oligopoly is a common market structure.
It arises from

The Prevalence of Oligopoly Oligopoly is a common market structure. It arises
the same forces that lead to monopoly, except in weaker form.
It is an industry with only a small number of producers.
A producer in such an industry is known as an oligopolist.

Слайд 5

The Prevalence of Oligopoly

When no one firm has a monopoly, but producers

The Prevalence of Oligopoly When no one firm has a monopoly, but
nonetheless realize that they can affect market prices, an industry is characterized by imperfect competition.

Слайд 6

Some Oligopolistic Industries

Some Oligopolistic Industries

Слайд 7

Understanding Oligopoly

Some of the key issues in oligopoly can be understood by

Understanding Oligopoly Some of the key issues in oligopoly can be understood
looking at the simplest case, a duopoly.
An oligopoly consisting of only two firms is a duopoly. Each firm is a duopolist.
With only two firms in the industry, each would realize that by producing more, it would drive down the market price. So each firm would, like a monopolist, realize that profits would be higher if it limited its production.

Слайд 8

Understanding Oligopoly

One possibility is that the two companies will engage in collusion.

Understanding Oligopoly One possibility is that the two companies will engage in
Sellers engage in collusion when they cooperate to raise each others’ profits.
The strongest form of collusion is a cartel, an agreement by several producers to obey output restrictions in order to increase their joint profits.
They may also engage in non-cooperative behavior, ignoring the effects of their actions on each others’ profits.

Слайд 9

Understanding Oligopoly

By acting as if they were a single monopolist, oligopolists can

Understanding Oligopoly By acting as if they were a single monopolist, oligopolists
maximize their combined profits. So there is an incentive to form a cartel.
However, each firm has an incentive to cheat—to produce more than it is supposed to under the cartel agreement. So there are two principal outcomes: successful collusion or behaving non-cooperatively by cheating.
When firms ignore the effects of their actions on each others’ profits, they engage in non-cooperative behavior. It is likely to be easier to achieve informal collusion when firms in an industry face capacity constraints.

Слайд 10

Competing in Prices vs. Competing in Quantities

Firms may decide to engage in

Competing in Prices vs. Competing in Quantities Firms may decide to engage
quantity or price competition.
The basic insight of the quantity competition (or the Cournot model) is that when firms are restricted in how much they can produce, it is easier for them to avoid excessive competition and to “divvy up” the market, thereby pricing above marginal cost and earning profits.
It is easier for them to achieve an outcome that looks like collusion without a formal agreement.

Слайд 11

Competing in Prices vs. Competing in Quantities

The logic behind the price competition

Competing in Prices vs. Competing in Quantities The logic behind the price
(or the Bertrand model) is that when firms produce perfect substitutes and have sufficient capacity to satisfy demand when price is equal to marginal cost, then each firm will be compelled to engage in competition by undercutting its rival’s price until the price reaches marginal cost—that is, perfect competition.

Слайд 12

The Prisoners’ Dilemma

When the decisions of two or more firms significantly affect

The Prisoners’ Dilemma When the decisions of two or more firms significantly
each others’ profits, they are in a situation of interdependence.
The study of behavior in situations of interdependence is known as game theory.
The reward received by a player in a game—such as the profit earned by an oligopolist—is that player’s payoff.
A payoff matrix shows how the payoff to each of the participants in a two player game depends on the actions of both. Such a matrix helps us analyze interdependence.

Слайд 13

A Payoff Matrix

ADM

Ajinomoto

Produce 30 million pounds

ADM makes $180 million profit

Produce 40

A Payoff Matrix ADM Ajinomoto Produce 30 million pounds ADM makes $180
million pounds

Produce 30 million pounds

Produce 40 million pounds

Ajinomoto makes $180 million profit.

Ajinomoto makes $200 million profit.

Ajinomoto makes $160 million profit.

Ajinomoto makes $150 million profit.

ADM makes $150 million profit

ADM makes $200 million profit

ADM makes $160million profit

Слайд 14

The Prisoners’ Dilemma

Economists use game theory to study firms’ behavior when there

The Prisoners’ Dilemma Economists use game theory to study firms’ behavior when
is interdependence between their payoffs. The game can be represented with a payoff matrix. Depending on the payoffs, a player may or may not have a dominant strategy.
When each firm has an incentive to cheat, but both are worse off if both cheat, the situation is known as a prisoners’ dilemma.
The game based on two premises: (1) Each player has an incentive to choose an action that benefits itself at the other player’s expense. (2) When both players act in this way, both are worse off than if they had acted cooperatively.

Слайд 15

The Prisoners’ Dilemma

Don’t confess

Don’t confess

Confess

Confess

Louise

Louise gets 2-year sentence.

Louise gets 5-year sentence.

Thelma gets

The Prisoners’ Dilemma Don’t confess Don’t confess Confess Confess Louise Louise gets
20-year sentence.

Thelma gets 5-year sentence.

Louise gets 15-year sentence.

Louise gets 20-year sentence.

Thelma gets 15-year sentence.

Thelma gets 2-year sentence.

Thelma

Слайд 16

The Prisoners’ Dilemma

An action is a dominant strategy when it is a

The Prisoners’ Dilemma An action is a dominant strategy when it is
player’s best action regardless of the action taken by the other player. Depending on the payoffs, a player may or may not have a dominant strategy.
A Nash equilibrium, also known as a non-cooperative equilibrium, is the result when each player in a game chooses the action that maximizes his or her payoff given the actions of other players, ignoring the effects of his or her action on the payoffs received by those other players.

Слайд 17

Overcoming the Prisoners’ Dilemma

Repeated Interaction and Tacit Collusion
Players who don’t take their

Overcoming the Prisoners’ Dilemma Repeated Interaction and Tacit Collusion Players who don’t
interdependence into account arrive at a Nash, or non-cooperative, equilibrium. But if a game is played repeatedly, players may engage in strategic behavior, sacrificing short-run profit to influence future behavior. In repeated prisoners’ dilemma games, tit for tat is often a good strategy, leading to successful tacit collusion.
Tit for tat involves playing cooperatively at first, then doing whatever the other player did in the previous period.
When firms limit production and raise prices in a way that raises each others’ profits, even though they have not made any formal agreement, they are engaged in tacit collusion.

Слайд 18

How Repeated Interaction Can Support Collusion

Tit for tat

Tit for tat

Always cheat

Always cheat

ADM

Ajinomoto

ADM

How Repeated Interaction Can Support Collusion Tit for tat Tit for tat
makes $180 million profit each year.

Ajinomoto makes $180 million profit each year.

Ajinomoto makes $200 million profit 1st year, $160 profit each later year.

Ajinomoto makes $150 million profit 1st year, $160 million profit each later year.

Ajinomoto makes $160 million profit each year.

ADM makes $150 million profit 1st year, $160 million profit each later year.

ADM makes $200 million profit 1st year, $160 million profit each later year.

ADM makes $160 million profit each year.

Слайд 19

The Kinked Demand Curve

An oligopolist who believes she will lose a substantial

The Kinked Demand Curve An oligopolist who believes she will lose a
number of sales if she reduces output and increases her price, but will gain only a few additional sales if she increases output and lowers her price away from the tacit collusion outcome, faces a kinked demand curve—very flat above the kink and very steep below the kink.
It illustrates how tacit collusion can make an oligopolist unresponsive to changes in marginal cost within a certain range when those changes are unique to her.

Слайд 20

The Kinked Demand Curve

Q

*

P

*

Quantity

Price, cost marginal revenue

X

W

Y

D

Z

MR

MC

2

MC

1

1. Any marginal cost in this

The Kinked Demand Curve Q * P * Quantity Price, cost marginal
region

2. … corresponds to this level of output

Tacit collusion outcome

Слайд 21

The Ups and Downs of the Oil Cartel

60

$70

50

40

30

20

10

Price of crude oil (per

The Ups and Downs of the Oil Cartel 60 $70 50 40
barrel)

Year

Crude Oil Prices, 1947-2007

(in constant 2006 dollars)

1947

1950

1960

1970

1980

1990

2000

2007

Iran-Iraq War

9/11/01

Gulf War

Iranian Revolution

Rising world demand and Middle East tensions

Yom Kippur War Arab Oil Embargo

Series of OPEC output cuts

OPEC 10% quota increase

Слайд 22

Oligopoly in Practice

Oligopolies operate under legal restrictions in the form of antitrust

Oligopoly in Practice Oligopolies operate under legal restrictions in the form of
policy. Antitrust policies are efforts undertaken by the government to prevent oligopolistic industries from becoming or behaving like monopolies. But many succeed in achieving tacit collusion.
Tacit collusion is limited by a number of factors, including:
large numbers of firms
complex products and pricing scheme
bargaining power of buyers
conflicts of interest among firms

Слайд 23

Product Differentiation and Price Leadership

When collusion breaks down, there is a price

Product Differentiation and Price Leadership When collusion breaks down, there is a
war.
To limit competition, oligopolists often engage in product differentiation which is an attempt by a firm to convince buyers that its product is different from the products of other firms in the industry.
When products are differentiated, it is sometimes possible for an industry to achieve tacit collusion through price leadership.
Oligopolists often avoid competing directly on price, engaging in non-price competition through advertising and other means instead.

Слайд 24

Product Differentiation and Price Leadership, cont’d

In price leadership, one firm sets its

Product Differentiation and Price Leadership, cont’d In price leadership, one firm sets
price first, and other firms then follow.
Firms that have a tacit understanding not to compete on price often engage in intense nonprice competition, using advertising and other means to try to increase their sales.

Слайд 25

Many industries are oligopolies: there are only a few sellers. In particular,

Many industries are oligopolies: there are only a few sellers. In particular,
a duopoly has only two sellers. Oligopolies exist for more or less the same reasons that monopolies exist, but in weaker form. They are characterized by imperfect competition: firms compete but possess market power.
Predicting the behavior of oligopolists poses something of a puzzle. The firms in an oligopoly could maximize their combined profits by acting as a cartel, setting output levels for each firm as if they were a single monopolist; to the extent that firms manage to do this, they engage in collusion. But each individual firm has an incentive to produce more than it would in such an arrangement—to engage in noncooperative behavior.

Слайд 26

The situation of interdependence, in which each firm’s profit depends noticeably on

The situation of interdependence, in which each firm’s profit depends noticeably on
what other firms do, is the subject of game theory. In the case of a game with two players, the payoff of each player depends both on its own actions and on the actions of the other; this interdependence can be represented as a payoff matrix. Depending on the structure of payoffs in the payoff matrix, a player may have a dominant strategy—an action that is always the best regardless of the other player’s actions.

Слайд 27

Duopolists face a particular type of game known as a prisoners’ dilemma;

Duopolists face a particular type of game known as a prisoners’ dilemma;
if each acts independently in its own interest, the resulting Nash equilibrium or Noncooperative equilibrium will be bad for both. However, firms that expect to play a game repeatedly tend to engage in strategic behavior, trying to influence each other’s future actions. A particular strategy that seems to work well in such situations is tit for tat, which often leads to tacit collusion.
The kinked demand curve illustrates how an oligopolist that faces unique changes in its marginal cost within a certain range may choose not to adjust its output and price in order to avoid a breakdown in tacit collusion.
Имя файла: Oligopoly-.pptx
Количество просмотров: 236
Количество скачиваний: 1